What is at Stake?
All else being equal, the growing demand for genetic and
biochemical resources should increase the potential market value of the raw
material. But, given the high revenues generated from the final products
developed in the agricultural and pharmaceutical industries, it is easy to
misjudge how much money might actually be involved.
Many of the industries using genetic and biochemical resources
produce high-value commodities and thus enjoy substantial gross earnings from
the commercial product. Two drugs derived from the rosy periwinkle - vincristine
and vinblastine - alone earned $100 million annually for Eli Lilly (Farnsworth,
1988) - a figure that is sometimes erroneously cited as the "value"
of the rosy periwinkle. But sales of a product provide little indication of the
potential market value of the unimproved genetic material in the source country.
Most of the industries using these resources are capital-intensive
ventures that invest substantial time and money in the production of a
commercial product, and most are far removed from the original source of the
genetic or biochemical material.
In the U.S. pharmaceutical industry, a commercially marketable
drug requires an estimated $231 million and 12 years on average to develop
(DiMasi et al., 1991). These costs cover the process of screening candidate
compounds, isolating active compounds, testing for possible toxicity, and
undertaking clinical trials, as well as failed attempts to discover and produce
a new drug. Developing agricultural products through genetic engineering also
entails substantial costs. For example, the successful introduction of Bt genes
into plants took several years and cost some $1.5 million to $3 million
(Collinson and Wright, 1991).
In any given trial, the likelihood of discovering a valuable
compound for the pharmaceutical industry is quite low. By most estimates, only
about one in 10,000 chemicals yields a promising lead, and less than one fourth
of the chemicals reaching clinical trials will ever be approved as a new drug
(McChesney, 1992; DiMasi et al., 1991; Principe, unpublished ms.). For example,
of 50,000 extracts put through an HIV screen in the natural products research
program of the National Cancer Institute, only 3 are likely to wind up in
clinical trials, and of 33,000 extracts screened for cancer only 5 are receiving
further study (Sears, 1992).2
Given the high value added in both the pharmaceutical industry and
agriculture, the abundance of unimproved genetic and biochemical resources, and
the low probability that any specific sample will have commercial value, the
holders of unimproved material are likely to receive a relatively low payment
for access to the resource, current heightened demand notwithstanding. In
agriculture, Barton (1991) estimates, the total revenue that might be gained if
developing countries sought royalties for unimproved genetic material could
amount to less than $100 million annually.3
Even in the pharmaceutical industry, possible earnings from the
sale of raw materials are smaller than might be thought given the
industry's worldwide sales of roughly $200 billion - more than 30 times
that of the seed industry (Lisansky and Coombs, 1989). In this industry, typical
royalties paid for samples of unknown clinical activity (e.g., new synthetic
chemicals) amount to only 1 to 5 percent of net sales - a range of royalties
likely to apply to natural products as well. Consider an institution that
supplies 1,000 chemicals to a pharmaceutical company in return for a 3-percent
royalty on the net sales of any commercial product. Given the need to screen
roughly 10,000 chemicals to find a single lead, a 1 in 4 chance of a lead being
developed into a commercial product, a 5-percent discount rate, a 10-year wait
before a product is ready to be marketed, and 15 years of patent protection
while it is being marketed, and assuming that a drug, if discovered, generates
$10 million net annual revenues, the present value of the agreement to the
supplier is only $52,500.4 More sobering, there is a 97.5 percent
chance that the 1,000 chemicals will not turn up any commercial product at all,
and if they do, royalty payments won't begin until more than a decade after
chemical screening commences.
However, the prospects for success are raised with natural
products, since any extract from a species will contain hundreds or thousands of
different chemicals that might result in a pharmaceutical "lead."
Moreover, the probability of success can be increased through the use of
multiple - and higher quality - screens. Thus, for natural products research
using current technologies, the probability of success could easily be ten times
that of the example above, and thus produce promising leads at a rate of about 1
per 1,000 samples.5 The probability of developing at least one
commercial product in the above example would then grow from 2.5 percent to 22
percent, and the present value of the agreement would grow accordingly, to
$461,000. And, if a "blockbuster" drug - earning $1 billion in sales
annually - happens to be discovered under this scenario, that value would swell
to $46 million.
Biodiversity prospecting does involve financial risks. With the
odds against striking it rich, it often makes economic sense for biodiversity
prospectors to hedge their bets by seeking advance payments and relatively small
royalties rather than forgoing collecting fees and holding out for higher
royalties that may never materialize. Moreover, a risk exists that the market
for natural products could quickly become saturated. While a number of
pharmaceutical firms have natural products research efforts under way (see
Table I.1), most are small in scale, and the demand for chemical
extracts from plants, animals, and microbes might be saturated by a handful of
large-scale suppliers. As, say, Costa Rica, Indonesia, India, Brazil, and Mexico
establish biodiversity prospecting institutes, the growing supply may well lead
to steadily declining prices for raw materials.
Finally, there is no sure way of projecting future demand for
biological samples on the part of the pharmaceutical industry. Within a decade
or two, advances in synthetic chemistry, biotechnology, and medical sciences may
curtail interest in natural products. On the other hand, wild species will
continue to be a source of novel genes and proteins, as well as a source of
insights into chemical and physiological processes. Nobody knows whether natural
products will fall from favor in several decades or become even more
valuable in medicine and in industrial applications.
In sum, while biodiversity prospecting can return profits to
source countries, institutions, and communities, the amounts involved are likely
to be small relative to the market value of the final products, a decade or more
may pass before significant revenues materialize, a good chance exists that no
commercial drugs will be produced, and late-comers may find a market already
saturated with suppliers. On the other hand, given the scale of revenues
generated in the pharmaceutical industry, even a relatively small share of net
profits may amount to extremely large revenues for a developing country. And, if
nations add value to genetic resources domestically and build technical capacity
for improving the resource themselves, biodiversity prospecting could become an
important component of a nation's economic development
strategy.