Development policy: overestimating the capacity to change things
Room for Manoeuvre: An Exploration of Public Policy in
Agriculture and Rural Development, edited by E.J. Clay and B. B. Schaffer.
Gower, Farnborough, 1985, 209 p., $13.50.
Radical critique of development politics is not new. For a long
time it was based primarily on Marxist or "dependency"-oriented studies,
stressing the close relationship between the "development business" and the
interests of the dominant classes in the industrialized countries. In the last
couple of years radical criticism has also emerged from a quite different
perspective: neoliberals attacking the inefficiency of state intervention which
distorts the salutary effects of market forces, distracts resources from
productive use, and inflates an unproductive bureaucracy. In contrast to the
often rather academic character of these approaches, this book, edited by Edward
Clay and the late Bernard Schaffer, promises a radical critique of development
politics from an insider's perspective and ideas on how to detect and use the
largest "room for manoeuvre" given in particular situations for pursuing
objectives which are in themselves mostly uncontroversial (fulfilment of basic
needs, increase of productivity, equitable land reform).
In an introductory chapter, the editors explain their concern
"to analyze public policy on development as the process and practice of what
governments actually do, to explain the linkages between intentions and
outcomes". For them the basic problem is the widely followed "common sense" or
"mainstream" model of public policy, which represents public policy as a
dichotomous linear process of two distinct but sequential phases, the process
leading to the decision for a particular policy and its implementation land the
problems related to it). This implies the fiction of an independent
decision-making process oriented exclusively toward particular development
objectives. The gaps between intentions and outcomes then appear to be due to
difficulties of implementation, thus apparently removing all responsibility from
policy-makers' shoulders. The target-group approach is seen as a logical
supplement to the described policy model: trying to improve the situation of a
specific social group, planners and politicians tend to base policies on highly
selective data and problems and thereby to isolate the target group from the
social development of which it forms part. Several case studies elucidate
particular problems and contradictions of the mainstream model. Percy Selwyn's
analysis of agricultural budgets in Mauritius shows that budgetary allocations
hardly imply any real policy decision but tend to be self-perpetuating: "Those
in society who would benefit from a re-ordering of priorities in expenditure may
have little information on what is required, and may in any event have little
political influence." Edward J. Clay demonstrates that the establishment of
"Special Planning Units" related to problems of foodcrops and nutrition in
Bangladesh and Sri Lanka might theoretically have contributed to a strengthening
of the planning process, but in practice had little impact on agricultural
development as they had not been integrated into the regular political process.
Rural women constitute one of the most typical target groups in recent years.
Florence McCarthy points out - commenting on such a programme in Bang ladesh -
that "with women treated as a separate issue much that could be done to
stabilize inputs onto the rural areas becomes fragmented." The role of women is
isolated and is entrusted to "urban-based women, who... know nothing about rural
women".
Perfect solutions, Stephen Biggs - in a survey of common themes
in agricultural policy - stresses the inadequacy of the dominant "normative
institutional engineering approach" to policy formulation, which proposes
abstractly perfect solutions to social problems without considering the
specificity of each local situation. Taking the example of a rural credit scheme
in Bangladesh, which serves landless labourers and poor rural women, Biggs shows
that the cautious evolution of such a scheme out of a locally conceived and
initiated action research project can help to promote the situation of the rural
poor. Two case studies on multilateral institutions {Martin Evans on change in
the strategy of the Asian Development Bank; Diana Hunt on the experiences of the
International Fund for Agricultural Development in Kenya) indicate that here the
gap between policy formation and implementation tends to be even larger as a
result of the tension between their international character and the attention
paid by member states to their own national sovereignty. Thus,
basic-needs-oriented concepts were at least in part converted back into
across-the-board assistance (Evans) or aid for middle and rich peasants (Hunt).
The third part of the book focuses on "The Languages and
Practice of Public Policy". A shorter contribution by Raymond Apthorpe stresses
the need for a comprehensive interdisciplinary approach recognizing the
existential character of development problems. The concluding article by Bernard
Schaffer - which occupies about a quarter of the book - summarizes the different
aspects of critique of the "mainstream" model and indicates ways toward an
alternative treatment of public policy, drawing on the results of the preceding
case studies and supplementing them with other examples. To me, his most
interesting criticisms were:
- on the compartmentalization of a social whole into apparently
independent sectoral realities;
- on the decisionality of the model suggesting that
well-considered, rational decisions have been taken, when, in fact, alternative
strategies were excluded long before (as in the case of the "decision" to drop
atomic bombs on Japan in 1945);
- on the manifold escapes from responsibility, frequently based
on the pretence that the results of carefully carried out academic studies did
not leave any other choice than the "chosen" policy.
Alternative models. Nevertheless, I finally finished reading the
book with a certain sense of frustration. In contrast to the extensive criticism
of the "mainstream" model, few indications are given of alternative policy
models to enlarge the "room for manoeuvre". These parts of the Schaffer article
remain vague. The alternative model has to have an inclusive character; the
attempt to make their own strategy unassailable has to be replaced by the
"willingness of the institutions to be involved with their critics" and to
organize the "process of alternative participation". I agree. But what does that
mean with respect to existing political structures and - even more fundamental -
what does it mean for the potential of development politics to modify prevalent
historical tendencies in favour of particular social objectives?
I suspect that one reason for the vagueness of the proposed
alternative model is to be found in an incomplete analysis of the state of
affairs. The editors never arrive at the question why, after all, the mainstream
model has dominated development planning. In a short joint conclusion, they
emphasize "that the whole life of policy is a chaos of purposes and accidents.
It is not at all a matter of the rational implementation of so-called decisions
through selected strategies". - This could be the clue to the whole problem:
development planning tends to overestimate its capacities to change the "normal"
course of history, to have an impact on what would have happened without the
planning effort - even seemingly successful strategies quite often just
successfully anticipate historical tendencies. This would suggest, first,
looking for some kind of development tendencies hidden behind the "chaos of
purposes and accidents" and then detecting the crossroads where appropriate
political intervention could possibly push the course of events into the desired
direction.
Wolfgang
Hein