Cover Image
close this bookThe Global Greenhouse Regime. Who Pays? (UNU, 1993, 382 p.)
View the documentList of contributors
View the documentPreface
View the documentAcknowledgements
close this folderPart I Measuring responsibility
close this folder1 Introduction
View the document(introduction...)
View the documentThe greenhouse effect
View the documentWhat was decided at Rio?
View the documentProtocol negotiating difficulties
View the documentKey issues for climate change negotiations
View the documentReferences
close this folder2 The basics of greenhouse gas indices
View the document(introduction...)
View the documentApples and oranges
View the documentImplications
View the documentConclusion: indices do matter
View the documentReferences
close this folder3 Assessing emissions: five approaches compared
View the document(introduction...)
View the documentIntroduction
View the documentComprehensiveness compared
View the documentAccuracy by category
View the documentRegional and national emissions by source
View the documentConclusions
View the documentReferences
View the documentAppendix A: Estimates of greenhouse gas emissions
View the documentAppendix B: Calculating cumulative and current emissions
close this folder4 Who pays (to solve the problem and how much)?
View the document(introduction...)
View the documentIndices of allocation: a brief review
View the documentAccountability
View the documentEquity and efficiency
View the documentConclusion
View the documentReferences
close this folderPart II Resource transfers
close this folder5 North-South carbon abatement costs
View the document(introduction...)
View the documentClimate change convention
View the documentMethod overview
View the documentImplications for the South
View the documentNotes and references
close this folder6 North-South transfer
View the document(introduction...)
View the documentObligation to pay indices
View the documentRedistribution of incremental cost
View the documentBenchmarks
View the documentUN scale of payments
View the documentFinancing mechanisms
View the documentConclusion
View the documentNotes and references
close this folder7 Insuring against sea level rise
View the document(introduction...)
View the documentInsurability of losses
View the documentOil pollution
View the documentNuclear damage
View the documentImplications
View the documentThe insurance scheme proposed by AOSIS
View the documentThe Climate Change Convention
View the documentNotes and references
View the documentAppendix: Scheme proposed by AOSIS for inclusion in the Climate Change Convention
close this folderPart III National greenhouse gas reduction cost curves
close this folder8 Integrating ecology and economy in India
View the document(introduction...)
View the documentIntroduction
View the documentEmissions inventory
View the documentEnergy efficiency and fuel substitution
View the documentEmissions and sequestration from forest biomass
View the documentConclusions
View the documentReferences
close this folder9 Carbon abatement potential in West Africa
View the document(introduction...)
View the documentIntroduction
View the documentLong-term energy and carbon emissions scenarios
View the documentOptions for rational energy use and carbon conservation
View the documentEconomic opportunities for implementation
View the documentPolicy issues for the region
View the documentConclusions
View the documentReferences
close this folder10 Abatement of carbon dioxide emissions in Brazil
View the document(introduction...)
View the documentBrazil energy economy
View the documentEnergy subsector analyses
View the documentChanging land-use trends
View the documentConclusion
View the documentReferences
close this folder11 Thailand's demand side management initiative: a practical response to global warming
View the document(introduction...)
View the documentIntroduction
View the documentEnd-use energy efficiency policies
View the documentCosts and benefits of the DSM master plan
View the documentCO2 reductions from the DSM Plan
View the documentWhy should other developing countries adopt DSM?
View the documentThe role of the multilateral development banks
View the documentConclusions
View the documentReferences
close this folder12 Carbon abatement in Central and Eastern Europe and the Commonwealth of Independent States
View the document(introduction...)
View the documentEnergy-environment nexus
View the documentScenarios for the future
View the documentCountry results
View the documentPolicy implications
View the documentConclusion
View the documentReferences
close this folder13 Greenhouse gas emission abatement in Australia
View the document(introduction...)
View the documentAbatement of energy sector emissions
View the documentEconomic impact of abatement strategies
View the documentNon-energy emission abatement
View the documentAustralia's international role
View the documentCarbon taxes, externalities and other policy instruments
View the documentReferences
close this folderPart IV Conclusion
close this folder14 Constructing a global greenhouse regime
View the document(introduction...)
View the documentConditionality and additionality
View the documentTechnology transfer
View the documentMulti-pronged approach
View the documentImplementation procedures
View the documentRegional building blocks
View the documentNorth-'South' conflicts
View the documentConclusion
View the documentNotes and references
close this folderAppendix: The Climate change convention
View the documentIntroduction
View the documentBackground
View the documentClimate change convention
View the documentArticle 1. Definitions
View the documentArticle 2. Objective
View the documentArticle 3. Principles
View the documentArticle 4 Commitments
View the documentArticle 5. Research and systematic observation
View the documentArticle 6. Education, training and public awareness
View the documentArticle 7. Conference of the Parties
View the documentArticle 8. Secretariat
View the documentArticle 9. Subsidiary body for scientific and technological advice
View the documentArticle 10. Subsidiary Body for implementation
View the documentArticle 11. Financial mechanism
View the documentArticle 12. Communication of information related to implementation
View the documentArticle 13. Resolution of questions regarding implementation
View the documentArticle 14. Settlement of disputes
View the documentArticle 15. Amendments to the Convention
View the documentArticle 16. Adoption and amendment of annexes to the Convention
View the documentArticle 17. Protocols
View the documentArticle 18. Right to vote
View the documentArticle 19. Depositary
View the documentArticle 20. Signature
View the documentArticle 21. Interim arrangements
View the documentArticle 22. Ratification, acceptance, approval or accession
View the documentArticle 23. Entry into force
View the documentArticle 24. Reservations
View the documentArticle 25. Withdrawal
View the documentArticle 26. Authentic texts

Economic impact of abatement strategies

One of the studies referred to above included estimates of the macroeconomic consequences of the proposed emission reduction measures (Australian Commission for the Future 1991). The ACF study is the one in Australia to date which integrates the results of 'bottom up', technology-specific energy modelling with a 'top down' macro-economic model. Two levels of abatement were analysed the demand side measures only, falling somewhat short of emission stabilization; and the demand and electricity supply measures combined, achieving the Toronto target, as described above. The major impact on the economy in both cases comes from the surge in investment expenditure needed to pay for the new, more efficient energy-using and energy-supply equipment. This strategy requires diverting economic resources from consumption to investment, with the result that consumption expenditures fall.

Since the ACF study found that most of the demand side measures were cost effective relative to expected energy prices, it is not surprising that aggressive deployment of these measures alone yields net macro-economic benefits over the long term, as measured by a slightly higher rate of GDP growth than in the base case. Achieving the Toronto target requires that Australia diverts a higher proportion of resources to energy-related investments and that the average unit cost of energy is higher than in the base case. Thus, GDP growth is lower than in the base case by between a half and one per cent, depending on assumptions about how the economy adjusts to change. This outcome is obviously a relatively small change, much less than the changes associated with the normal ups and downs of economic activity. One reason for the change being so small is the study's assumption that Australia takes a unilateral decision to limit greenhouse gas emissions. Domestically produced fossil fuel resources, particularly coal and petroleum, are therefore available to be exported if not required for domestic consumption.

Other economic studies have sought to model the effects of measures to reduce greenhouse gas emissions on the Australian economy or particularly vulnerable sectors of it, most of which have been summarized by the Industry Commission (1991). These studies share the following common features:

1 a 'top clown' approach to modelling the Australian energy economy;
2 the use of a carbon tax as the policy instrument by which emission abatement will be achieved;
3 a focus on the cost of achieving only the Toronto target, with no analysis of the costs of lower levels of abatement;
4 no allowance for improvements in technology which could increase the efficiency of energy supply and use without increasing costs.

This approach assumes that all markets for energy services are perfectly competitive, that is, energy is used throughout the economy with optimal technical efficiency and no cost-less opportunities for efficiency improvement are available. It follows that an increase in energy prices by means of a carbon tax is needed to induce any change in technical efficiency. Of course, this assumption varies sharply from the findings of the sectoral energy use studies described above.

Disagreement over this issue is by no means confined to Australia, but is a persistent theme around the world in debates over energy and greenhouse emissions (see for example Manne and Richels 1990; Williams 1990; Nordhaus 1991). Some have characterized this as a disagreement in perspective between economists and engineers. It could perhaps be more accurately described as a disagreement between those who sit behind desks and theorize about the economy; and those who go out to visit factories and building sites and talk to people who are making decisions about energy-using equipment.

The most detailed study of this kind was undertaken by the Industry Commission (IC) itself (1991). The IC estimated that a carbon tax of A$80 (1988 prices) per tonne of carbon (equivalent to about US$60 per tonne) would be required to reduce emissions to the Toronto target. A tax at this rate was found to reduce GDP by 2 per cent. The effect on the output of the energy industries was considerably greater - the output of the coal industry fell by 26 per cent, that of the electricity industry by 11 per cent, and of the gas industry by 19 per cent. This last result diverges strikingly from the results of the bottom up, technology oriented studies, which project an increase in gas industry output as gas is substituted for coal and electricity. It would appear that the substitution elasticities (between factors of production and between fuels) used in the macro-economic model used for this study do not accurately represent the realistic technical possibilities available in the Australian energy system. The IC recognizes the inadequacies of the modelling approach it has used, commenting that the work has been undertaken for 'illustrative purposes'.

Not surprisingly, given the different assumptions, this estimate of the GDP cost of abatement is somewhat higher than that from the previously cited ACF study. The Industry Commission study assumed that the revenue raised by the carbon tax would offset direct taxes (income tax and company tax). Somewhat surprisingly, it did not model the effect of offsetting the carbon tax by reducing another consumption tax or related tax, such as payroll tax, which is currently the focus of some policy debate in Australian politics. A recent study of the US economy concluded that a moderately severe gasoline tax (a form of one-sector carbon tax) would depress GDP and consumption if the revenue were used to reduce either the budget deficit or direct taxes, but would have virtually no effect on economic activity if used to reduce payroll taxes (Brinner et al, 1991).