DEMAND OR HARM REDUCTION
Efforts to reduce demand for illicit drugs include both
sanctions and incentives. Sanctions focus on law enforcement initiatives meant
to apprehend and deter consumers through fines, jail sentences and loss of
privileges. Positive incentives have also been developed to offer people reasons
to cease, or at least greatly to reduce, illicit drug use. The combination of
sanctions and incentives is meant to create a climate wherein non-users are
reluctant to take up the habit. Aside from law enforcement initiatives designed
to raise risks for consumers, the demand reduction strategies of principal
consuming countries have focused on popular education in the classroom and
through the mass media, initiatives in the workplace, civic action,
anti-contagion treatment programmes and efforts to develop an anti-drug ethos.
Intensifying the negative component of demand reduction
strategies through increased reliance on prohibition, combined with law
enforcement efforts that are increasingly tough on users, is likely to be
effective only among two types of people: those who have something of value to
lose and those who see themselves as having a future worth sacrificing for.
Crack cocaine and heroin users who are members of the underclass
might therefore not be much affected by such strategies.
Initiatives in the workplace to reduce consumption are
principally based on drug testing, with threats of dismissal if positive results
are returned. This strategy is unlikely to reduce demand for drugs among the
burgeoning number of inner city crack users, arguably the greatest problem in
the United States, and perhaps elsewhere. This approach presumes that the drug
user wants employment and has it, that the employer values the employee and that
they both have an incentive to work together to create a drug-free workplace.
All these factors are unlikely to coalesce among unskilled, low-skilled or
minimum-wage employees, who are usually quickly replaceable and are themselves
likely to drift from job to job.
Education is one of the primary elements of the positive
component of demand reduction strategies. If education within the classroom is
to reduce demand, it needs to be coupled with community-wide integrated efforts,
including the dissemination of explicit anti-drug values and peer modelling
begun at a fairly early age. The mass media in several consuming nations have
had some success in targeting certain audiences for such anti-drug campaigns.
Civic action is also a way to reduce demand for illegal drugs.
Helping people to build homes, assisting the long-term unemployed to acquire
skills and find jobs, creating educational and other opportunities for children
in poor communities are activities in which communities have engaged, and which
have had a positive impact on their drug problems. Raising community support for
voluntary anti-drug service is a first step, but effective co-ordination is
required to ensure that acceptable goals are pursued in productive ways. Some
communities are attempting to orchestrate this co-ordination. In Detroit,
Michigan, a community in one of the citys abandoned-house districts has
launched an effort to purchase crack houses, renovate them and sell
them at low cost to senior citizens and single parent families who need housing
and can be relied upon not to participate in the drug trade. Other community
initiatives include self-help groups for addicts and an anonymous hotline for
residents to report drug-related activities in their neighbourhoods without fear
that their identity will be revealed.
Another demand reduction strategy involves treatment programmes,
which are thought by some to be useful not only for addressing the addiction of
individuals, but also for reducing the spread of drug addiction. The assumption
underlying treatment as a strategy to reduce consumption is that drug addiction
spreads like a contagious disease: most people become drug users and perhaps
eventual addicts because friends have introduced them to the practice, pushing
drugs to support their own addiction. Therefore, successfully treating addicts
removes their economic need to market drugs to acquaintances and eliminates a
large partof the reason for the spread of drug addiction. Accordingly, proposals
have been made - by law enforcement officers, among others - for considerably
more funding for drug addiction treatment programmes.
Finally, efforts have been made to develop an anti-drug
ethos as a means of reducing demand. One of the strongest deterrents to
the use of illicit drugs is peoples conviction that drug use is
inappropriate, whether for moral or utilitarian reasons. If the fundamental
values of a specific group of people change in ways which disfavour drugs, the
reduction in consumption will be more lasting. This kind of value change is more
likely to be brought about by persuasion than by coercion. Thus calls are made
for the mobilization of community efforts to re-establish eroded social values
and to provide substantial social incentives for people to reform their
lifestyles.
All direct demand reduction options concentrate on users and
assume that illicit drug use may be reduced by approaches that invoke fear, self
interest or value change. An indication of drug policy priorities in the United
States is given by the allocation of expenditures in the country: 75 per cent of
total drug control expenditure goes for repression of consumption and supply,
compared to 25 per cent for prevention, education, research and treatment. So
far, an emphasis on fear (e.g. fear of jail and of property losses) has formed
the basis of consumer-focused demand reduction policies. Not surprisingly, fear
strategies work best on those in the middle class whose employment and property
are at risk. Such policies have had no proven drug consumption effect on the
economic underclass where much hard-core drug abuse takes
place.