Financing of new enterprises
Surveys of small and medium scale rural enterprises in
Bangladesh (Ahmed 1984, for example), other South Asian countries, and Africa
frequently reveal that financing constraints are binding. But closer examination
of the findings uncovers equivocation, both with respect to need, as well as
local availability (Aryeetey, et al 1995). Proposals about remedying the
situation have become more hedged as experience has accumulated. Cross-country
evidence suggests that entrepreneurs draw personal savings and, if possible, the
resources of the extended family to set up an enterprise. Thereafter, profits
are the main source of funds for expansion. Small firms in Africa and Bangladesh
do obtain some working capital from informal sources, credit cooperatives, and
banks. They also receive credit in the form of raw material advances from
suppliers and advances from their customers (Islam and others 1994). Because
most borrowers cannot supply collateral and banks have difficulty ensuring
repayment, banks rarely extend term financing for equipment and structures.
Likewise, although rotating savings and credit associations (ROSCAS) are
widespread in Asian and African countries, they rarely contribute directly 36 to
the development of small-scale industry. They do not contribute mainly because
the amounts involved are fairly small (Jaffee 1994) and because the loans are
mainly used for consumption purposes. But if these associations are able to
spread and strengthen the ethic of disciplined saving, as in Taiwan (China)
(Besley and Levenson 1993), then they can indirectly encourage rural
industrialization by increasing household demand for durables. The message is
that very small pools of institutional finance do not have a discernible effect
on rural industrialization. Only when the pools expand do they enter the
picture, either through market demand or, as in China, by enabling
community-managed rural cooperatives to finance industry.
In Africa low rates of rural household savings have rendered
ROSCAS ineffectual for industrial purposes. Household savings are higher in
Bangladesh, in areas where the Grameen Bank, which requires that borrowers save,
is active. But these efforts will be a slow process, and will probably work
through the demand side rather through direct industrial financing. Does that
mean that financial instruments are ineffectual or irrelevant? The Bank's record
of lending to small and medium-sized enterprises shows that the cost per job
created was US $4,000 in Asia and nearly US $10,000 in Africa (Webster 1994).
Programs involving development banks were ineffectual, and lending for technical
assistance yielded slim returns. But if the local business environment was
buoyant and a base of supportive institutions was functional, financing through
competent banks or NGOs produced good results.
Continuing to improve savings, investment, and exports would
spur the rural industrialization in Bangladesh. Institutions such as Grameen
Bank, BRAC, and BSCIC can serve as conduits for financing and extension, with
commercial banks also playing a larger role. A deliberate attempt to stimulating
rural industry around a small number of strategically located growth poles can
ensure the needed supply of services. Lending by the World Bank and other
donors, which gave rise to an interlinked cluster of rural enterprises, could
start a virtuous circle if early success generated a strong demonstration
effect.