Government intervention
2.64 In circumstances where private supply of goods and services
remains below the social optimum and where market, contractual, and cooperative
mechanisms fail to effectively coordinate production and marketing activities,
there may be justification for government interventions. Interventions by the
State can reduce the risks and transaction costs faced by private firms and
individuals, can compensate for missing or deficient markets, and can influence
the organization and performance of commodity systems so as to enhance the
benefits to the country or to particular interest groups (e.g. consumers,
farmers, manufacturers). Government intervention need not entail direct
government provision of goods and services. Regulation, taxation, and
subsidization are alternative modes of intervention. As relatively few food
marketing activities have public good properties, it is these types of
interventions, rather than direct government participation, which are usually
more appropriate.
2.65 The government has certain fundamental roles to play, these
being either areas where only a sovereign body has the legitimacy or capability
to act or areas where, for economic or technical reasons, the private sector
will have insufficient incentives to provide a good or service at socially
optimal levels. One of these fundamental roles lies in the definition and
consistent enforcement of a reasonable set of property rights and regulations
pertaining to acceptable and non-acceptable competitive and cooperative actions.
Such property rights and regulations should not only facilitate production and
trade, but also protect consumers against misleading claims and
health-threatening foods.
2.66 A second fundamental role of government is to negotiate and
define the rules for international trade and market entry. Governments can
negotiate, either in bilateral or multilateral forums, to facilitate a
particular commodity transaction (e.g. a deal with a state importing company) or
to arrange longer term access for national firms to foreign markets on terms
equal or superior to those accorded to competitive suppliers. At the same time
(and usually under the influence of domestic interest groups), governments must
determine the general rules for foreign entry into domestic input, financial,
and commodity markets. Such rules will influence the competitiveness of food
commodity systems vis-a-vis imported products as well as the availability and
costs of production and other resources.
2.67 A third fundamental role of governments is to directly
undertake or support the provision of goods and services which have public good
properties, give rise to significant externalities, or feature economies of
scale which are so significant as to result in natural monopolies. This pertains
to several forms of physical and social infrastructure, including roads, rail
and port facilities, power and water systems, technical research and training,
and selected quality control and market information services. Because of the
inherent economic properties of such goods and services, private supply may not
be profitable or at least may not result in a socially optimal level of supply.
While many governments have directly provided such goods and services, other
options are to subsidize private supply, contract out supply to the private
sector (thus assuring payment for services), or provide particular private or
cooperative organizations with exclusive supply rights (e.g. on utility supply)
or coercive powers (e.g. on quality control).
2.68 There are many other common types of government
interventions in commodity systems. While of a less fundamental nature, these
interventions can serve to counter market imperfections, reduce or alter the
distribution of risks, influence the volumes and prices of traded products,
and/or influence the distribution of opportunities and income. Comments follow
on a sample of such common interventions.
2.69 Governments sometimes attempt to compensate for missing or
deficient markets. This is particularly common in the area of credit where risk
factors and major information imperfections are at play. Weak credit markets may
result in limited funds available for small-scale farmers, cooperatives, and
commodity traders, and for farmers and firms seeking to invest in assets
carrying long gestation periods or being 'lumpy' in character. Being less
risk-averse, governments may be better positioned to extend credit for these and
other commodity system participants. An 'infant industry' argument for
government support may be applicable in the early stages of development of
particular commodity systems.
2.70 Another service commonly provided by governments is price
stabilization. Stabilized prices can be regarded as a public good for farmers,
consumers, processors, or other commodity system participants. Price
stabilization-involving such instruments as price controls, floor prices, buffer
stocks, variable taxes, and quantity controls-- is ostensibly undertaken in
order to lower the risks and stabilize the incomes of producers and/or
consumers. However, price stabilization is often very costly to undertake,
generates allocative distortions, and can adversely affect producer or trader
incentives.
2.71 Still other government interventions are geared toward
influencing the competitive structure of markets, thereby affecting the volume
and value of trade and the distribution of income. Regulations may be geared
toward promoting or protecting a competitive market structure or conversely,
toward promoting the concentration or monopolization of trade. The former would
be more common in a domestic market setting-in the interface between farmers and
processors or at wholesale or retail levels. The latter is more common in
export-oriented industries where economies of scale and improved bargaining
power can be achieved through some degree of trade concentration.
2.72 Where voluntary cooperation fails to control 'free riders',
capture the benefits from scale economies, or enable suppliers to exercise
market power, governments can institute schemes for compulsory cooperation. The
most common and well-documented forms of compulsory cooperation are one-channel
procurement and sales through marketing boards, and supply and pricing controls
through marketing orders (Jesse (1979); Hoos (1979). Both marketing boards and
marketing orders can be used to control physical commodity flows, enforce
quality standards, and pool market risks.
2.73 With monopoly export marketing boards, an entire commodity
system can 'behave' like a single firm vis-a-vis the world market, regulating
the mix and quality of products going to different markets and negotiating with
transporters and buyers with a single voice. While export marketing boards can
achieve certain economies of scale, pool producer and processor risks, and
provide a means for asserting or countering international market power, the
boards can become a major barrier in the flow of information between foreign
buyers and local producers and processors. In addition, export marketing boards
can become either the tool of certain vested interest groups (e.g. the political
leadership, influential farmers, or processors) or an unstable arena in which
various interest groups battle over policies and the spoils of trade (Bates
(1981); Arhin et al. (1985)). In either case, marketing board policies may
result in reduced production incentives and a processing and marketing strategy
which is not demand-oriented and thus not sustainable in a competitive world
market.
2.74 Table 5 summarizes this discussion by indicating whether
the noted technologies or institutional mechanisms facilitate improved commodity
and other flows, reduce raw material procurement and market risks, internalize
externalities, etc.

Technological/Institutional Measures
to Facilitate Commodity System Coordination, Efficiency and Market
Power