![]() | Exporting High-Value Food Commodities: Success Stories from Developing Countries (WB, 1993, 119 p.) |
![]() | ![]() | III. Synthesis high-value food commodity system ''Success stories'' |
![]() | ![]() | Commodity system organization coordination |
3.41 This section provides a synthesis of major institutional/organizational patterns in the case study commodity systems. We examine the competitive structure within these systems, the primary institutional linkages between producers and processor/exporters and between the latter and foreign market buyers/agents, and the roles played by foreign private companies and by local producer or trade associations.
3.42 Table 14 summarizes the competitive structure of production, processing/packing, and domestic distribution and exporting in the case study subsectors. Production or trade is denoted as 'Highly Decentralized' if it features numerous firms or individuals, with the largest ten accounting for less than 50% of supplies, processing capacity, or sales. An operation is labelled an 'Oligopoly' if the ten largest firms or individuals account for more than 50% of the market. A label of 'Concentrated Oligopoly' is given to operations in which five or fewer firms control 75% or more of the market. The label 'Monopoly' refers to an exclusive processor or trader. The indicated structures are those which prevailed during the mid-to-late 1980s. It is recognized that a concentrated structure is not a sufficient condition to suspect the presence of collusive and anti-competitive practices.
3.43 The table shows that while production and domestic marketing are generally highly decentralized, most cases feature relatively high levels of concentration at the packing or processing stage and most especially in export marketing. This pattern is not unexpected given the economies of scale in processing and export logistics and sales and the high transaction costs associated with international trade.
3.44 Virtually all of the subsectors have developed with the participation of large numbers of crop, fish, or animal product producers. In some cases, including Kenyan vegetables, Israeli citrus, Thai poultry, Thai and China shrimp, and Taiwanese vegetable and pork sub-sectors, farm producers number in the thousands and generate operate on a small-to-medium scale. Still, technological changes, economic pressures, and vertical integration by input suppliers or downstream marketing enterprises into production have contributed to increased concentration in production over time in some of these sub-sectors. Export-oriented fruit production in Chile and soybean production in Brazil and Argentina has been undertaken by relatively large numbers of middle- and especially large-scale farmers and agribusinesses. Only one of the focal cases has featured a very narrow production base. Export-oriented fresh tomato production in Mexico has remained the preserve of about a dozen local companies, due to preferential access to water resources, government-delegated powers to regulate (export-oriented) tomato plantings and sales, and favorable ties to U.S. vegetable distributors. The Thai tuna canning industry is unique among our cases in that it relies upon imported fish for 70% of its raw material requirements.
3.45 Domestic marketing of the focal commodities remains highly competitive in most of the focal subsectors, even where export marketing has become concentrated among a few firms. Domestic marketing systems have often featured the wide participation of cooperatives, brokers, and small-to-medium scale private firms, in addition to a handful of larger wholesaler/distributors. In a number of cases (including Argentine beef and soybeans, Mexican tomatoes, and Thai shrimp), large auctions or terminal markets have enhanced the competitive environment of local markets. Direct marketing between producers and either retail chains or restaurants/hotels has also emerged in a number of these cases.
Table 14: COMPETITIVE STRUCTURE OF COMMODITY SYSTEMS
Commodity System |
High Decentralized |
Oligopoly |
Concentrated Oligopoly |
Monopoly |
Mexico Fresh Tomatoes | |
Production | |
|
| |
Packing | |
|
|
Local Sales |
Exporting | |
|
| | | | |
Kenya Fresh Vegetables |
Production |
Packing | |
|
| |
Exporting | |
|
Chile Temperate Fruits |
Production |
Packing | |
|
| |
Exporting | |
|
Israel Citrus |
Production |
Processing |
Packing |
Export |
Chile Processed |
Production |
Processing | |
|
Tomatoes | |
Exporting | |
|
Brazil FCOJ |
Production | |
Processing | |
| | |
Exporting | |
Thailand Poultry |
Production |
Processing | |
|
| |
Local Sales |
Exporting | |
Argentina Beef |
Production |
Processing | |
|
| |
Exporting | |
|
|
Local Sales |
| | |
Chile Fish |
Production |
Processing/ |
| |
|
Processing/ |
Exporting of |
| |
|
Exporting Fish |
Fish Oil/Meal |
| |
Thailand Tuna |
Production | |
Processing | |
|
(Imported) | |
Exporting | |
Thailand Cultured |
Production | |
| |
Shrimp |
Processing | |
| |
|
Local Sales |
| | |
|
Exporting | |
| |
China Cultured Shrimp |
Production |
Processing | |
|
|
Local Sales |
|
Exporting | |
Taiwan (China) Vegetable, |
Production | |
| |
Pork, and Fish Processing |
Processing | |
| |
|
Local Sales |
Exporting | |
|
Brazil Soybeans |
Production | |
| |
|
Processing | |
| |
|
Local Sales |
| | |
|
Exporting | |
| |
Argentina Soybeans |
Production |
Processing | |
|
|
Local Sales |
Exporting | |
|
3.46 While there are a few exceptions, fresh produce packing, processing, and exporting have tended toward oligopolistic structures with between three and ten firms accounting for the bulk of operating capacity and sales. In one-third of our cases (e.g. Israeli citrus, Brazilian FCOJ, Thai poultry and tuna, and Chinese shrimp), three firms or less have recently accounted for 75% or more of total exports. In such cases as Kenyan vegetables, Chilean temperate fruit, and Thai tuna and poultry, concentrated trade structures have resulted largely from economic factors, with a limited number of firms taking advantage of superior technical or financial resources and overseas market linkages to acquire leadership positions within their industries. Having invested in modern packing and/or processing facilities and having effectively penetrated overseas markets, such firms have been better able to adapt to changing market requirements.
3.47 In several other cases, the concentration of trade has derived from government interventions as much as from economies of scale or other underlying economic factors. For example:
--In Mexico, the government has given the National Commission of Vegetable Producers and individual state producer unions the power to control planted acreage, export licenses, and export volumes so to exercise market power in the United States and maintain the profitability of the Mexican industry. Powerful members in these producer unions have been able to control entry into export-oriented tomato production and to consolidate their own positions.--In Israel, several laws and regulations adopted in the 1940s created a marketing cartel in the form of the Citrus Marketing Board which incorporated many of the larger pre-WWII exporters as contractors to the Board and as members, together with government representatives, of the Board's decision-making committees. By operating as the sole buyer and seller of Israeli fresh citrus, the CMBI was designed to achieve economies of scale in the procurement of inputs and in export logistics and to assert Israel's market power in Europe for selected fruits during certain months. This cartel faced serious difficulties as its members had widely differing interests with regards to the quality and types of fruits to market, the timing of sales, and the patterns of grower remuneration from a price pool.
--In China, initially an export monopoly for shrimp was given to the National Cereals, Oils, and Foodstuffs Import and Export Corporation and later (in 1985) shrimp and other food export rights were granted to provincial foreign trade corporations (all state enterprises).
--In Brazil, government credit programs and the periodic imposition of export quotas (based on past exports) contributed to the consolidation of a three-firm dominance of the FCOJ industry with some degree of price coordination in international markets.
3.48 In the focal commodity systems, various institutional arrangements have been developed to coordinate raw material production with processing and other downstream requirements. These patterns are summarized in Table 15, which represents a 'snapshot' of important institutional arrangements prevailing in the late 1980s. The Table indicates that while in the majority of cases there are open market linkages between some producers and processors/exporters, only in two cases is arms-length trade the dominant mode of raw material procurement. In the case of Argentine beef, a well-established system of auctions, terminal markets, and brokerage arrangements (dating back more than 50 years) facilitates a steady and massive movement of cattle from producers to slaughterhouses and processors. In the case of Thai tuna, Bangkok's fish markets have become amongst the largest and well-developed in Southeast Asia, providing Thai canners with a steady and large supply of different tuna species caught both in the Indian and Pacific Oceans. In all other cases, market coordination has been supplemented or replaced by a combination of other modes of vertical coordination, including seasonal (or longer term) contracts, ownership integration, cooperative coordination, and/or government coordination.
Table 15: Institutional Arrangements Linking Producers with Processors/Exporters
Commodity System |
Market Coordination |
Contract Coordination |
Ownership Integration |
Cooperative/ Association Coordination |
Gov't Coordination |
Mexico |
X |
X |
XX |
X |
X |
Tomatoes | |
| | | |
Kenya Fresh |
X |
X |
X | | |
Vegetable | |
| | | |
Chile Temperate |
|
XX |
X |
X | |
Fruit | | | | | |
Israel Fresh |
|
XX | |
X |
X |
Citrus | | | | | |
Chile Processed |
X |
XX | | | |
Tomatoes | |
| | | |
Brazil FCOJ |
|
XX |
X | |
X |
Thailand Poultry |
X |
XX |
X | | |
Argentina Beef |
XX |
X |
X | | |
Chile Fish |
X |
X |
X |
X | |
(Meal/Oil) | |
| | | |
Thailand Tuna |
XX |
X | | |
X |
Thailand Cultured |
|
XX |
X |
X | |
Shrimp | | | | | |
China Cultured |
|
X |
X | |
X |
Shrimp | | | | | |
Taiwan (China) |
| | |
| |
Pork |
X |
X | |
X | |
Vegetables |
X |
XX | |
X | |
Brazil Soybean |
X | | |
X | |
Argentina Soybean |
X |
XX | |
X | |
XX denotes the dominant linkage in the industry
3.49 Contractual coordination is important in all of the case studies involving fresh and processed fruit and vegetables as well as in the Thai poultry and shrimp sub-sectors. While the actual contractual arrangements vary, most feature the supply of credit and/or production inputs, a forward or formula pricing mechanism, and specifications regarding the quantity, quality, and timing of producer deliveries. Such arrangements have improved the flow of information, technologies, money, and physical commodities between producers and processor/exporters and facilitated a sharing of production and/or market risks.
3.50 Many of the subsectors feature at least some vertical integration between production and downstream activities. This has normally been undertaken by relatively large processing/trading firms in order to reduce raw material supply risks and costs or by larger farmers seeking to capture a larger share of the export revenues. In both the Thai poultry and shrimp cases, individual firms have developed operations integrating feed supply, production, processing, and trade. In many cases, processors have combined own production with contracted outgrower supplies so to achieve a preferred mix of cost economizing and risk spreading. In general, the export-oriented components of individual sub-sectors have exhibited far more 'intensive vertical coordination than production and trade for domestic markets. However, in many cases the contractual and other coordinating methods used by exporters are being increasingly adopted in the domestic market, especially by producers and firms targeting higher-quality, higher-price market segments.
3.51 Cooperatives or producer and trade associations have played an important marketing and coordination role in several of the case study commodity systems. In the Mexican case, both the National Union of Vegetable Producers and the Confederation of Agricultural Associations of the State of Sinaloa have played important coordinating roles, not only through their assignment of acreage and export quotas, but also in their dissemination of market information, their assistance in agricultural inputs procurement, their enforcement of tomato quality standards, and their liaisons with government water authorities. In Taiwan (China), cooperatives have played a very important role in the domestic marketing of smallholder fruit, vegetable, and pork production and in the exports of fresh fruit and vegetables. The same holds true in the Argentine and Brazilian soybean sub-sectors. Producer and trader associations have been active in establishing quality standards, negotiating producer prices, and settling disputes in the cases of Chilean fruit and fish and Thai shrimp.
3.52 In several cases, government trading or regulatory agencies have played a role in coordinating production and downstream operations. The pattern for Mexican tomato exports has already been discussed. In Israel, the Citrus Marketing Board gave annual supply quotas (specifying quantities, varieties, and delivery times) to a limited number of private or cooperative packing/production companies which in turn had annual supply agreements with many individual farmers. In Brazil, the government periodically intervened in negotiations and disputes between growers and processors, seeking to work out appropriate methods for allocating market risks and determining producer prices. In the case of Thai tuna processing, the Thai government has coordinated government controlled fresh tuna supplies from the Maldive Islands.
3.53 Table 16 summarizes the institutional linkages (during the mid-to-late 1980s) between exporters in the focal subsectors and foreign market buyers or agents. Once again, the table indicates that while open market sales occur in each case, such sales constitute the dominant linkage to foreign markets in only three of the commodity systems. Spot market sales or sales on consignment are very important in the exports of Chilean temperate fruits, Israeli citrus, Argentine beef, Brazilian and Argentine soybeans, and PRC shrimp. In all but the last of these cases, shipments are made over very long distances to well-developed markets, featuring major wholesale outlets or mercantile commodity exchanges. Until recently, the bulk of Chinese shrimp exports have been undertaken either at periodic trade fairs in the country or via Hong Kong commercial agents.
Table 16: Institutional Arrangements Linking Exporters with Foreign Buyers/Agents
Commodity System |
Market Coordination |
Contract Coordination |
Ownership Integration |
Government Coordination |
Mexico Tomatoes |
X |
X |
XX | |
Kenya Fresh Vegetable |
X |
X |
X | |
Chile Temperate Fruit |
X |
X |
X | |
Israel Fresh Citrus |
X |
X | | |
Brazil FCOJ |
X |
XX | | |
Thailand Poultry |
|
X |
XX | |
Argentina Beef |
XX |
X |
X |
X |
Thailand Tuna |
X |
X |
XX | |
Thailand Cultured Shrimp | |
X |
X | |
China Cultured Shrimp |
X | | |
X |
Brazil Soybean |
XX |
X |
X |
X |
Argentina Soybean |
XX |
X |
X |
X |
XX denotes the dominant linkage in the industry
3.54 At least a portion of trade in nearly all the cases occurs in the context of seasonal, annual, or other contracts. Some 80% of Brazil's FCOJ exports to the U.S. are conducted within the framework of long-term contracts with multinational beverage manufacturers/distributors. While most of the subsectors feature some trade conducted on an intra-firm basis by local or multinational companies, such intra-firm trade is dominant in the cases of Mexican tomatoes and Thai poultry and tuna. Approximately 60% of the vegetable distributors based in Nogales, Arizona (the U.S. entry point for most Mexican winter vegetables) are partners with Mexican producing/packing companies, while 20% of these distributors are owned outright by Mexican firms. Three Japanese companies handle virtually all of Thailand's exports of frozen chicken parts to Japan. Thailand's leading tuna canners have integrated forward into major markets, buying up leading import/distribution firms. Approximately 25% of Kenya's fresh vegetable (and fruit) exports are conducted with overseas firms which are affiliated through familial ties with Kenyan exporters.
3.55 These long-term contractual ties or ownership linkages have been important in maintaining market access, in penetrating rapidly expanding marketing channels (e.g. for retail chains), in obtaining detailed and up-to-date information on market conditions and consumer tastes, in reducing uncertainties regarding payments, and in assuring continuity of supplies so to benefit from (national or foreign) brand name promotion. In circumstances where product demand and/or distribution channels needed to be built up from an only rudimentary base, such personalized trade or ownership linkages provided an effective framework (See Box 6). In several cases, including Mexico tomatoes, Chile fruit, Brazil FCOJ, Argentina beef, Thai poultry, and Brazil soybean, long-term foreign trading partners have actively campaigned for continued supplier access to industrialized country markets in the face of pressures by domestic producers for protection against imports.
Box 6: Developing a Market Through Personalized Trading Networks For the past quarter century, one of the core components of Kenya's expanding horticultural has been the export of needy two dozen "Asian vegetables. (including chilies, karela, okra, dudhi, etc.) to the United Kingdom to serve that country's expanding Asian minority communities. development of this trade was built upon a series of highly personalized trading relationships, quite distinct from the mainstream U.K. fruit and vegetable marketing system. Beginning in the 1960s and continuing through the 1970s, there was a rapid expansion in the UK's population of individuals of South Asian ethnic origin. Fueled by immigration as well as relatively high birth rates, this population reached 550,000 in 1971 and over one million by 1980. Exhibiting a preference for certain traditional foods and lacking acceptable local substitutes for many these foods, there developed a large tin-met demand for a wide range of fresh vegetables which, for agro-climatic reasons, could not be grown locally. An import trade in "Asian vegetables first emerged in the early 1960s when several small-scale Indian merchants began receiving produce consignments from India and selling this produce from the parking lot of Heathrow Airport. Within a few years, Kenya would replace India as the primary "Asian vegetable" supplier. Kenya's entry into this market was eased by the fact that most of that country's leading produce exporters were Asian owned family companies with experience in the production and trade of "Asian vegetables ". By the early 1970s, some of the parking lot importers acquired vans and began making deliveries to London-based retailers; others developed wholesale distribution centers nearby to the primary mainstream wholesale markets. Still, the trade remained small and the market undeveloped, especially outside of London. This would change in 1973, when a senior partner in Kenya's largest fresh produce company emigrated to the U.K. anti established his own import/distribution company. This firm would re-shape the 'Asian vegetable' market by developing a network of secondary wholesalers and retailers within London and distribution networks within the major cities id the Midlands. The firm's family-affiliated supplier in Kenya responded to the market opening by rapidly expanding supplies. This integrated export - U.K. distribution operation soon became the leading actor in this market, setting the standards for quality and strongly influencing the levels of import end wholesale prices. By the late-1970s, Kenya's other leading produce exporters also developed highly personalized, long-term trading arrangements with selected importer/distributors in the U.K. In some cases, the trading firms were linked by family ties; otherwise, connections: were made through mutual friends and business associates. Both on the Kenyan and U.K. sides, the primary actors in this 'Asian vegetable' trade remained small-to-medium scale Asian-owned family operations. Whether or not there were family ties, the typical framework for trade was seasonal contracts specifying the range of products to be traded, required quantities and delivery days, negotiated fixed prices, and payment arrangements. Most Kenyan exporters developed and maintained trade links to buyers based in several . different cities so to achieve wider distribution and minimize direct competition among their buyers. These personalized and long-term trading arrangements facilitated improved information flows, lowered exporter markets risks and buyer procurement risks, reduced the risks faced by - exporters of importer payment failure or false quality claims, enabled the: firms to bypass exchange controls and otherwise take advantage of currency fluctuations, and enabled the firms to undertake joint efforts to test and promote new commodities. Secure exporter-importer ties provided the confidence to exporters to expand their trade and diversify their product range and the confidence of importers to search out new distribution change, including those serving multiple-chain retailers. |
3.56 As indicated earlier, in several of the cases, governments have either directly negotiated deals with foreign government importing agencies or have negotiated access and entry terms for private exporters into foreign markets. Those signified in the table relate only to direct trade deals.
3.57 Foreign capital, technology, training, and management skills have played an important role in the development of many of the focal commodity systems, especially during their initial 'take-off' stages. The primary roles of foreign companies or international donor agencies is summarized in Table 17.
Table 17: Foreign Capital and Technology in Commodity System Development
Commodity System of Material |
Production/ Direct Inputs |
Financing/Direct Investment in Production |
Direct Investment in Processing/Marketing Facilities |
Other Capital or Technology Transfer |
Mexico Tomatoes |
Seeds, Agro-chemicals |
Major Financing of Production |
Yes; Plus Financing of Packing Operations |
Private Training |
Kenya Vegetables |
Seeds |
Minor Direct Investment |
Minor |
Private Training |
Chile Fruits |
Seedlings Irrigation Technology |
Direct Investment |
Direct Investment |
University Training and Technology Exchange; Donor Financing Donor Financing for Irrigation and Orchard Rehabilitation |
Israel Citrus |
Seedlings |
Some Direct Investment | | |
Chile Processed Tomatoes |
Seeds | |
Direct Investment |
|
Brazil FCOJ |
Processing Equipment |
Direct Investment |
Major Direct |
University Training |
|
| | |
Investment and Exchanges |
| | | |
Donor Financing for Infrastructure |
Thailand Poultry |
Feeds, Vaccines, |
Financing through Contract |
Major Direct |
Farm Management |
|
Breeding Stock |
Farming |
Investment |
Training; Food |
|
| | |
Technology R&D |
Argentina Beef |
Breeding Stock |
Direct Investment |
Direct Investment |
|
Chile Fish | |
Off-shore Fishing by Foreign | | |
| |
Vessels | |
|
Thailand Tuna |
Processing Equipment |
Fishing by Foreign Vessels |
Direct Investment |
Management Training |
Thailand Shrimp |
| | |
Technology/Management Training; Food Technology R&D Technical |
China Shrimp |
Seedstock Production |
| | |
|
Joint Venture |
| |
Assistance |
Brazil Soybeans |
Seeds, Tractors |
Direct Investment |
Major Direct |
Technology Training |
|
| |
Investment |
Donor financing for infrastructure |
Argentina Soybeans |
Seeds, Tractors |
| |
Technical Assistance |
3.58 In virtually all of our focal cases in Latin America, credit from foreign distributors or direct foreign investments in production and/or processing and marketing facilities played a major role in the initial subsector growth. It was less important in our other cases (except for Thai poultry) and generally occurred in later stages of subsector development, serving to alleviate an existing bottleneck (e.g. feed shortages and high prices in the Chinese shrimp industry) or to augment the operating capacities of already competitive industries. In all of the focal cases, local companies have continued to account for a majority of exports, with multinational corporations accounting for 25 % or more of exports only in four cases-- Chilean fruit, Thai poultry, and Brazilian FCOJ and soybean.
3.59 Most of the subsectors initially relied upon imported technologies in the forms of planting materials, seed and breeding stocks, tractors, and processing plant and equipment. In most cases, at least some of these inputs and technologies were subsequently produced locally, either through licensing arrangements or through direct investments by international suppliers. Transfers of important technologies have also taken place through university or private training programs and joint or foreign programs of food technology R&D. In this regard, the most notable case is that of Chilean fruit
3.60 Bilateral or multilateral development finance organizations appear not to have played any role in directly supporting production and marketing of the focal commodities. However, at least in the cases of Israeli citrus, Chilean fruit, and Brazilian soybeans and FCOJ, loans or grants from such institutions did contribute to the development of production, marketing, and/or transport infrastructure (e.g. irrigation facilities; rail/port facilities) which was subsequently used for the focal commodities, among others.