Turning to the private sectorslowly
Industrial and middle-income countries have had considerable
success changing the ownership structure of public enterprises and involving the
private sector directly in the construction, management, financing, and
increasingly the partial or complete ownership of public enterprises. Low-income
countries, too, have planned and embarked on a range of similar activities
but so far in a more restrained and limited manner and with far more limited
results. In Kenya, only 5 of 200 public enterprises designated for privatization
in 1991 had been sold by the end of 1993. In Bangladesh, of 40 firms slated for
sale in 199.1, only 9 had been privatized as of March 1994. And while 29
reforming African countries have privatized a fifth of their nearly 3,000 public
enterprises, the economic weight of those soldmeasured by turnover,
investment, or employmentwas far lower. Privatizations almost everywhere
take longer than planned. And many countries have scaled back optimistic
ambitions in light of experience. But the process has been even slower and more
problem-filled in lowincome countries, where caution, slippage, and delays in
both enterprise reform and private sector development programs are common.
The reasons lie in a series of vicious circles common and
powerful in lowincome countries. Because private sectors were weak, governments
pinned their hopes on public firms. But as the shortcomings of public
enterprises have become more evident, there still is no private sector of
sufficient size, experience, and wealth to turn toin large part because of
the emphasis placed on public enterprises. Because the bulk of credit has been
directed from state-owned banks to state-owned firms, capital markets suffered
relative neglect. Now that divestiture is on the agenda, few low-income
countries have more than embryonic equity markets (though, encouragingly, these
are on the rise in a range of low-income countries: for example, China, India,
Kenya, Pakistan, Sri Lanka, and Zimbabwe).
Public enterprises have provided bureaucrats politicians and
regime loyalists with income supplements, power, and myriad opportunities for
illegal gain
Policymakers in some low-income countries are reluctant to
privatize or increase the role of the private sector because they mistrust the
managerial capacity of the public sector. They resist private involvement and
divestiture because they have little faith in the capacity of the public
administrative system to conduct transparent transactions, to regulate private
monopolies, to collect corporate taxes on privatized firms, and to adjudicate
disputes and enforce contracts. Thus, the managerial weakness of the state is
cited, paradoxically, to justify the state's continued direct involvement in
managing productive entities.
The dominance of the state in the economy means that few good
employment opportunities exist outside the state structure. And people within
the state apparatus often lack the experience and skills that open doors in the
private sector. Moreover, public enterprises have provided bureaucrats,
politicians, and regime loyalists with income supplements (sitting fees for
board membership, for example), power (to obtain and hand out jobs), and myriad
opportunities for illegal gain. Those being asked to diminish state dominance
are precisely those who will pay a high and direct material price if the
policies are applied. Even when bold leaders overcome all these problems and put
forward a comprehensive reform package, they frequently find they are not
supported administrative institutions are weak and understaffed, and
implementation capacity is lacking. So, the reform founders.
It is hard in low-income countries to find a catalytic core of
people not dependent economically on the state. In middle-income and industrial
countries, state-diminishing reforms have been led by political figures relying
on stakeholders whose economic base lay outside the state structureon
economic actors who saw the advantages of less-fettered private initiative. And
in transition economies, radical reformers were able (at first) to tap a large
vein of anti-state sentiment because the previous regimes were seen as foreign,
repressive, or both.
Given the lack of a popular base with the power, the will, and
the means to support reforms, liberalizing reformers in low-income countries
have been fewer, their task more difficult, and their voices more muted. Workers
and farmers, who will eventually reap the benefits of liberalization, are
dispersed and unorganized. And their enthusiasm for the reforms is usually
minimal often because the benefits of reform are not fully passed on to
them but siphoned off along the way. For the average citizen, the costs of
reform are apparent and immediate, the benefits uncertain and future. All this
means that reform and privatization are hard to sell (but see box 3. 1).
The upshot of all this is a major development dilemma.
Low-income countries have the greatest need for increased private sector
involvement in their enterprises. But the factors that produce that need are
those that make it difficult to launch, hard to implement, and hard to bring to
fruition.
The picture is not uniformly bleak. Some governmentsoften
with the assistance of IDA operationshave applied the commercialization
package of public enterprise reforms more rigorously than in the past (see box
3.3). And while efforts to involve the private sector in public enterprises have
been difficult to launch in low-income countries, they have by no means been
entirely absent. Many public enterprise sales have been completed in Benin,
Mozambique, Nicaragua, Nigeria, Senegal, Sri Lanka, Togo, and other lowincome
countries. Low-income countries actually pioneered some of the cutting-edge
developments in infrastructure privatization outside Europe. For 30 years, the
water supply of Abidjan in Cote d'Ivoire has been successfully managed by a
private firm. Concession operations of this naturenow once again very much
in favor worldwideare in existence or in the advanced planning stage in
several other lowincome countries, including Cape Verde and Guinea. .
What this shows is that the question for low-income countries is
not what should be donethe "what" is fairly well known. The key question
for lowincome countries is "how":
· How to apply more
widely the methods and techniques working well elsewhere and already showing
promise in low-income settings.
· How to protect the private
investor against government's changing the rules halfway through the game.
· How to build up the regulatory
and guardian institutions to protect the public against the abuse of private
economic power.
· How to garner broadly based
support, or at least build a powerful coalition of reformers, to initiate and
push through reforms long enough to show positive
results.