Public Expenditures
Public expenditures on family planning in developing countries
were estimated by several sources for 1990 at US$4-5 billion and are somewhat
higher now (World Bank, 1993a). However, these estimates are difficult to make
with confidence. Apart from the vagaries of government budgetary data in
developing countries, the estimates are complicated by the difficulty of
separating family planning from other health services, by the multiplicity of
agencies involved in family planning and the many channels through which they
may be funded, and to some extent by the definition of what activities should be
counted. For the Cairo population conference, UNFPA (1994) estimated the cost of
family planning programs in the year 2000 at US$10.2 billion and then added
US$5.0 billion for reproductive services that can be provided as part of primary
health care; US$1.3 billion for prevention of sexually transmitted diseases,
including HIV/AIDS; and US$600 million for population data collection, analysis,
and policy development.1
1Agency estimates of needed resources in
their areas should normally be treated with caution and some skepticism. The
family planning cost estimate appears somewhat high in comparison with 1990
estimates (on which there is reasonable consensus), but the reproductive
health-services cost estimate is undoubtedly far too low. Various joint costs
are counted under family planning rather than reproductive health (and further
development of the methodology for apportioning costs is needed). In addition,
the estimates for reproductive health are not meant to cover emergency obstetric
services above the primary health-care level, which are critical in reducing
maternal mortality. No comparable estimates of overall costs developed
independently of funding agencies are available.
Expenditures are usually tied to the number of users and are
expected to grow as the reproductive-age population grows - by about 2 percent a
year currently, although the rate will slow to 1 percent around 2015. But one
also has to allow for changing program costs. The initial years of a program
require the heaviest investment; as the number of contraceptive users grows, it
can become easier to serve them. But additional expenditures may be necessary to
maintain the program's momentum and to reach new user groups, as well as to
improve service quality and expand related reproductive health services.
Public family planning expenditures are quite variable across
countries in comparison to public expenditures on health. Estimates around 1989
suggest that family planning is most often around 2 percent of the government
health budget. However, many of the countries covered in these estimates have
quite weak programs, and the proportion goes up to 20-30 percent for some
extensive (and suc -cessful) programs, such as those in Indonesia and Bangladesh
(Ross et al., 1993). Some countries have therefore had considerable scope to
fund their family planning programs out of health budgets, but others have
required considerable outside assistance.
Funds from international donors cover a fourth to a third of
public expenditures on family planning throughout the developing world (the
overall proportion is low because China and India provide so much of their own
family planning resources). Donor commitments - designated support for
population and family planning from industrial countries, as well as funds
passing through multilateral institutions and development banks, plus funds from
private donors - fluctuate from year to year. They appeared to increase
substantially, to US$1.37 billion, the year after the 1994 Cairo conference (as
they did after the previous world conference in 1984). However, comparisons are
complicated by the expanded mandate from the Cairo conference to tackle
reproductive health, funding for which was counted for the first time in 1995
and found to comprise 23 percent of donor commitments. Not counting such
funding, donor commitments actually fell from 1994 to 1995 (by 7 percent in real
terms; funding trends in current dollars are shown in Figure 13). Even counting
reproductive health funding, substantially larger increases will be needed to
meet the Cairo conference goal of donor support for a third of the cost of
population and reproductive health programs by 2000 (UNFPA, 1997b).
Per capita, developing countries receive US$0.15 from
international donors for population and reproductive health programs, but
regional variation is considerable. Sub-Saharan Africa (with its relatively
newer programs and smaller populations) receives more and absorbed almost 80
percent of the increases in 1995, and Asia (with older programs and larger
populations) receives less (Figure 14).

Figure 13 - Trend in Donor
Assistance for Population Programs and Goal for 2000 (billion U.S. $)
SOURCE: UNFPA (forthcoming) for trend and UNFPA
(1994) for goal.
Government and donors do not cover all the costs of family
planning. Households pick up some proportion of the costs, about as much as
donors do, by one earlier estimate (Bulatao, 1985). In countries where
commercial contraceptive supply is limited, the contraceptives available are
unaffordable for most. But prices at pharmacies and smaller outlets decline as
the number of users increases, and price decreases do stimulate demand (Lewis,
1985). The cost of public programs also goes down. The cost per user of
program-supplied modern methods may be estimated roughly at US$20, but may range
from US$50 to under US$15 as the number of contraceptive users increases (Figure
15).
To assess whether there are cheaper ways to reduce fertility,
comparisons are sometimes made between family planning and other development
interventions. For instance, the cost-effectiveness of family planning for
reducing fertility has been contrasted with that of primary schooling for girls
in 16 countries, mostly Asian and Latin American. The median cost of averting a
birth through a family planning program, at US$58, was much lower than the
median cost of averting a birth through female education, at US$548 (Cochrane,
1988).2 A similar comparison of family planning with several
child-survival initiatives, including immunization, maternal and child health
programs, and infant and child feeding programs, gave a similar result. The
lowest-cost alternative among these mortality-reduction initiatives was still
more expensive, per birth averted, than family planning, with only one exception
across countries (measles immunization in Kenya). The median cost for family
planning was again about a tenth of the median cost for mortality reduction
(Cochrane and Zachariah, 1983).
2Average costs were used because marginal
costs were not available.

Figure 14 - Trend in What
Developing Regions Receive per Capita in Donor Support for Population Programs
(constant 1990 U.S. $)
SOURCE: Estimated from UNFPA
(forthcoming).

Figure 15 - Program Cost per
Contraceptive User by Number of Users, Selected Countries
SOURCE: Unpublished studies of the EVALUATION
Project at the University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill.
Such comparisons are seriously limited, since only the fertility
effect, not the other effects of the interventions, is taken into account.3
What they point to, nevertheless, is the inability of general education
and health programs to satisfy unmet need directly. Instead, they create over
time a general desire for smaller families and the social climate in which such
desires can be realized and therefore are a useful complement to family planning
programs and have contributed powerfully to fertility decline. But their effects
involve long lags: The long delay between a girl's schooling and her
childbearing, and the many things that must intervene to allow her to limit her
fertility, as opposed to the relatively immediate effects of family planning
programs, account for the latter's advantage in such comparisons as those above.
3Knowles (1997) considers this "the main
shortcoming of this type of analysis ... that the alternative investments
compared to family planning provide a wide range of private and social benefits
not incorporated into the analysis, so that the exercise risks being
irrelevant." Arguably, however, family planning also provides a range of other
benefits besides lower fertility, such as reduced mortality (for which its
cost-effectiveness is noted below). Knowles does make other important points in
his broad critique of such work, noting, for instance, that the alternatives to
government financing are seldom clearly modeled. In addition, data for
comparative analyses, such as the specific ones cited, always have some
deficiencies.