Alternative development
20 'Alternative development'2 must go much
wider than crop substitution, to cover broad-based economic, social and
institutional assistance to drug producers, often marginal groups of people
living on marginal land. It is acknowledged that in the past narrowly focused
alternative development projects have not worked because of poor design, a
failure to integrate projects with farmers' livelihood strategies, inappropriate
technology and poor market links. In the medium to long term, the best prospect
for alternative development is pro-poor macro-economic growth which reaches (in
some cases because of affirmative measures on the part of government) remote,
poor areas; this should be supported by micro-level interventions (e.g. in
education, information, infrastructure).
21 Donor support for alternative development can provide
political support to governments trying to develop more effective anti-drugs
policies (though it is important that donor support be well co-ordinated, with
clear, shared objectives). Governments may be encouraged to address the issues
affecting drug-producing communities described in paragraphs 7-10 above. Farmers
may be prepared to trade higher incomes for increased stability and security.
But alternative development must also be closely linked to a policy of
interdiction which increases the risk of drug crops production, disrupts the
supply chain and thus reduces the returns to the farmer.
22 Among issues to be considered in assessing alternative
development projects are the following:
· Alternative
development projects often have drug eradication conditionality attached to
them, i.e. farmers can benefit from development assistance on condition that
they reduce or eradicate drug crops. Views differ on the value of such
conditionality. Farmers may reject it on the grounds that it will deprive them
of a livelihood until alternative development is proven to work. Conditionality
can also lead farmers to identify alternative development projects with
repression. Eradication only works when it is voluntary, consensual and
accompanied by real alternatives for producers.
· Alternative development
projects often take place in a highly charged context involving strong political
and economic interests (those of central government, farmers' organisations,
drug traffickers, international governments and occasionally terrorist
organisations). Such interests greatly increase the risks of alternative
development projects.
· Some alternative development
projects are targeted to the areas of labour supply for drug crop production, to
reduce migration into the area. Such projects are often poorly targeted and
limited by difficult conditions and the high degree of geographic dispersion of
migrants. In order to reduce the 'balloon effect' (illicit drug cultivation
being suppressed in one area only to appear in a neighbouring area) better
understanding of on and off-farm needs for income generation is called
for.
23 Experience has shown that it is best to work with
communal institutions and local governments, rather than individual farmers. The
participation of women can often be a crucial factor for success. It would be
useful to explore the role which might be played by micro-credit schemes in
underpinning alternative development.
24 DFID currently supports alternative development
projects in Bolivia (a UNDCP/FAO agroforestry project) and Pakistan (a UNDCP
rural development project) and has recently approved support for a UNDCP rural
development project in Peru. Given the need for a co-ordinated donor effort, it
would be sensible to continue to look for opportunities to co-finance
alternative development projects through UNDCP (see paragraphs 35 - 37 below),
on the basis of concerted objectives and approaches. Opportunities should be
considered on a case-by-case basis, in the context of commitment by partner
governments to wider pro-poor
strategies.