7.3.1 Projects to provide new shelter
The case studies referred to in this report have reinforced
evidence from many countries that governments are not, by and large, as
efficient at acquiring, developing and managing land as the private sector or
community groups. By concentrating on projects, governments have failed to
develop their potential to regulate land and property markets through indirect
fiscal or regulatory mechanisms. Emphasis should therefore be given to projects
that provide the basis for developing and implementing support strategies in
which the role of the public sector is to complement and regulate the activities
of private-sector developers and community groups. In the case of new shelter
provision, this could initially involve joint ventures with formal and informal
private-sector developers and NGOs. These could take several forms, as outlined
below.
The first form of such joint ventures is that private sector
developers, together with land-owners should be enabled to prepare proposals to
develop any new area, providing they meet social policy objectives. The new
developments should preferably, but not necessarily, be located in areas
scheduled for future urban development. In return for planning permission to
develop part of the site, the developer and land-owner would agree to provide
some of the land to the local authority for the development of low-income
shelter or, alternatively, would itself provide some plots to standards and at
selling prices deemed by the local authorities to be affordable to low-income
groups. The actual proportion reserved for such low-income housing development
would vary according to the commercial potential of the location and negotiating
capability of the local authority. Clearly, safeguards would be required to
ensure that such arrangements were efficiently administered and not open to
abuse. For this reason, it may be considered appropriate to determine the
proportion of low-income plots in advance. This, however, may discourage
developers and land-owners from presenting any proposals at all, if they find
the potential profit margins unattractive.
The second form to be mentioned is lease-back projects. These
deserve emphasis in areas where land is commonly held under customary
land-ownership arrangements. These enable public-sector authorities to gain
access to land for development by leasing it from its owners at nominal rent for
a specified period. The land is then developed at the expense of the public
sector to meet commercial and social policy objectives, before it is returned to
its original owners at the end of the lease period. Such projects have already
been implemented in parts of Asia with considerable success.
Land-readjustment, land-pooling and land-sharing projects are a
third form of such joint ventures. Such projects have been undertaken
successfully in several countries, though the Republic of Korea possibly has the
greatest experience.5 These projects have improved the efficiency of
land markets, but they seem to have made only a marginal impact on access for
low-income groups.
5/ See Angel and Chirathamkijkul (1983)
and Archer (1987) for examples.
Sites-and-services (or area-development) schemes are the fourth
and last form to be mentioned here. They have been placed at the bottom of the
list of approaches deserving emphasis for several reasons. They are already
being implemented by public-sector agencies throughout the world and therefore
can no longer be considered innovative. They have also lost their original
radical potential of encouraging local authorities to move away from direct
provision towards enabling approaches and have instead become routine components
of direct provision. Despite these limitations, however, sites-and-services
remain as an approach that could still contribute to innovations in shelter
delivery for the poor. One means of achieving this would be to increase the size
of projects so that they can support the establishment of local project offices
based at the project site and working in multi-disciplinary teams. Larger
projects would also increase the prospects of including commercial and
industrial activities and could also attract middle and higher income groups
into a project. All of these would improve the potential for achieving
self-financed, but affordable, development, thus creating settlements that are
heterogeneous and dynamic places in which to live. The Rohini and Hai el Salam
projects are good examples of progress in this field. An even greater potential
benefit of sites-and-services projects is their ability to attract secondary
investment by private-sector developers. By locating projects in areas of
intended urban growth, they can serve to generate a multiplier
effect considerably greater than their direct contribution to supply. So
far, local authorities have generally failed to appreciate, let alone harness,
these secondary effects. They thus deserve emphasis as a means of expanding the
relevance of existing project approaches.
Whatever combination of the above is deemed appropriate in
specific cases, the primary objective of all new shelter projects should be to
reduce entry costs to levels that compete with those currently available
elsewhere, such as through the informal sector. This will enable low-income
households to enjoy a genuine choice and enable them to obtain access to secure
yet affordable shelter.
The second objective should be to use projects as a means of
testing alternative standards, regulations or procedures for developing land and
providing shelter. In this way, they can become a creative means of moving from
individual actions towards structural interventions in urban land and housing
markets.
The third objective should be to offer a range of options in
terms of plot size and shape, levels of initial services and allowances for
house costs for any given total cost level. This is because important planning
decisions usually will have been made before the residents arrive on a site and
opportunities for community participation are therefore likely to be limited.
Simply by offering three options in terms of plot size, services provision and
initial building standards within a given cost range would provide nine options
that can enable households to assert their preferences and priorities.
Monitoring the most popular options can then provide evidence for changing
official standards and regulations at urban or national levels.
The fourth objective of new shelter projects should be to
stimulate the supply of new residential plots to a level that approximates to
new household formation. This will improve availability and is the only long
term means of restricting land and house price inflation. In many cases, it will
require comprehensive changes to speed up the procedures for acquiring,
developing and allocating land for residential
use.