(introduction...)
This question encompasses some of the worlds most hotly
debated policy issues. Should stronger interdiction campaigns be undertaken
against drug producers and traffickers? Should economic incentives, educational
campaigns and other activities be undertaken to encourage people to change their
behaviour as consumers or producers? Should the war on drugs be
declared to have been misconceived, and expanded discussions be undertaken about
some controlled form of decriminalization and legalization?
Responses vary according to peoples values and views. The
primary focus of drug control policies in most parts of the world has heretofore
been on supply suppression through drug crop eradication and disruption of
trafficking channels. It is becoming increasingly clear, however, that North
America, Western Europe and other net consuming regions are unlikely to solve
their illicit drug consumption problems through the continuation of current
supply suppression strategies. Despite the expenditure of billions of dollars on
controlling supplies, the successful capture of major traffickers and
dismantling of their drug empires, and the weaning of peasant growers away from
coca and opium via alternative crop incentives, the global supply and
consumption of drugs has continued to grow.
The reasons for the failure of current drug control policies are
numerous: the lack of alternative income-earning possibilities among rural
people in net producing countries is too substantial, the price differential
between licit and illicit crops is too great, the huge profits acquired by
traffickers in illegal business are too enticing, and traffickers are too
skilled at eluding law enforcement efforts. If supply suppression is successful
in one area, crop production or drug refining activities quickly move elsewhere.
Moreover, even if supply suppression policies are successful in
increasing the costs of supplying drugs, and reducing the amount of drugs on the
market, consumption will only be reduced under certain conditions. Assuming
consumption to be price responsive (a condition that does not always hold),
prices can be driven up beyond peoples willingness or ability to pay only
if true scarcity relative to demand is created. A well-known study undertaken by
the Rand Corporation has suggested that, because the price of the coca leaf
accounts for less than 1 per cent of the retail price of cocaine, even a crop
eradication programmeable to triple the cost of production to the growers would
raise cocaine prices in the United States by no more than 1 per cent. The same
study indicates that, even if interdiction programmes were to become vastly more
successful, and were able to intercept 50 per cent of the cocaine arriving from
Colombia, US street prices would rise less than 3 per cent.
In most cases where supply control strategies have been
implemented, grower and trafficker counter-strategies have been more than
sufficient to maintain supplies on the market. In the United States, for
example, in spite of the large tonnage of illicit drugs confiscated every year,
drugs are as plentiful now as ever, and are sold at more affordable prices. In
Colombia, despite the destruction of the Medellsyndicate, drug production
continues as usual. Medells markets, resources, stocks and many of its
personnel have been incorporated into the rival Cali syndicate, making it now
the worlds leading cocaine trafficker.
Crop suppression strategies have been no more effective than
efforts to control drug trafficking. Experience shows that pressure placed on
growers is not sufficient to reduce drug crop production significantly. In
Bolivia, interdiction efforts against processors and traffickers have brought
down the price of coca leaves, leading to a slight drop in the amount of coca
produced since 1989. In Peru, however, coca production increased between 1989
and 1992 by an amount equivalent to 73 per cent of Bolivias reduction. It
is likely that one countrys success in reducing production will simply be
anothers problem as traffickers, refiners and intermediaries migrate to
places of least resistance and most opportunity, creating a demand for drug crop
production. This phenomenon is referred to as the balloon effect:
what is pushed down in one place simply springs up in another.
In some countries, cash rewards have been paid to growers who
voluntarily eradicate their crops, in order to compensate them for their loss of
income. However, in Bolivia for example, many of these growers simply moved to
new areas and planted new drug crops in more remote areas, or eradicated only
those crops that were old and unproductive. This has led many experts to argue
that crop eradication should be rewarded not with monetary compensation, but
with other crops or income-generating opportunities, or with social
infrastructure such as better roads and services.
Another obstacle to successful crop eradication is lack of
sufficient funds. National governments often argue that they cannot implement
eradication programmes unless they have strong financial backing from
international organizations and governments in the developed world. They
frequently complain that the amount of money needed to replace drug-based
economic activities is not forthcoming. But the funding agencies are reluctant
to release large sums of money unless they are convinced that national
governments are serious about implementing drug suppression programmes.
The fact that supply suppression, both absolutely and as a
surrogate for consumption control, seems to be a general failure at present
levels of investment in drug control indicates a need to re-examine drug control
policies. The following sections examine the main types of strategies that have
been proposed: (a) the intensification of crop suppression and interdiction
efforts through greater militarization of the war on drugs; (b)
greater implementation of alternative development strategies meant
to wean growers away from drug crops; and (c) demand or harm reduction in
consuming countries, including controlled legalization or
decriminalization.