Fertility and agriculture: Part of the Nexus?
Fertility is highest in rural areasreflecting economic and
sociocultural factors which affect fertility aspirations. Traditional lineage
and kinship systems, gender roles, and intergenerational relations contain
strong pronatalist forces, and women's fertility usually is a major determinant
of their status. Extended families, where the costs of high fertility are only
partly borne by the couple making the fertility decision, tend to encourage high
fertility. In most of rural SSA, labor is not readily available for hire and
must be mobilized from within the household or through social or kinship
arrangements specific to the community. For men, polygamy (or polygyny) is a
widely practiced way of securing the labor of women and their childrenbut
even women may welcome co-wives as co-workers (e.g., Netting 1993:89).
Polygamous men generally have more children than monogamous men, while women in
polygamous marriages tend to have fewer children than those in monogamous
marriages (Bongaarts and others 1990:135-136).
Women may recognize far more readily than men the costs of high
fertility to their own and their children's health. This may be particularly
prevalent in polygamous unions where each woman is responsible for her own
children. The costs of children are lower to men than to women, yet the value of
child labor may be higher to the mothers than to the fathersexcept in
communities where fathers have and assert priority rights to their children's
labor. For women, the labor of their children is often the only means of
securing adequate labor to cope with their many responsibilities. (In many
communities, women try to ease their peak labor constraints by participating in
various forms or kinship- or community-based work group and labor exchange
arrangements.) As water and woodfuels become more scarce and the time required
to obtain them increases, the need increases for children to help with the
mothers' growing workload associated with these survival activities. Child labor
is also increasingly needed to compensate for declining male labor in food crop
production, particularly in poor families that cannot hire wage labor. This may
contribute to the persistence of high fertility rates.7 In much of SSA, men and
women cultivate different crops on separate plots, and women's farming systems
depend heavily on female and child labor. Most women marry at an early age and
often considerably older men. Coupled with the high rates of divorce/separation
and the fact that in most African societies women can gain access to critical
assets (such as land) and public services only through male relatives, this may
increase women's willingness to bear many children so as to have sons to turn to
when husbands leave or die. The desired number of children is considerably
higher among rural women in Sub-Saharan Africa than among their counterparts in
any other region of the world. And in no other region of the world do women play
as significant a role in agriculture as in Sub-Saharan Africa.
The characteristics of most traditional land tenure systems may
also bear upon fertility decisionsbut more research is needed to establish
this link. Where access to land for farming is granted to all members of a
community, this may be a disincentive to fertility control. Where the amount of
land allocated is based on the ability to cultivate it, this ability -- under
the low-resource farming conditions prevailing in most of Sub-Saharan Africa
is primarily determined by the ability to mobilize labor. In most cases,
this means family labormore specifically, female and child labor. Indeed,
a number of field studies report this to be an important incentive to increase
family size through such means as polygamy and pressure on women to have many
children.
Among groups with matrilineal descent and inheritance
traditions, further complications may arise because land use rights are not
passed on from fathers to their children, but to uterine relatives (in most
cases males). This weakens the link between land availability and land resource
management on the one hand and demand for fewer children on the other. It also
weakens men's incentives to invest in maintaining the fertility of the land they
farm.8 Fathers may see little point in preserving farm land in good condition
beyond their own lifetime or in having few children so as to pass on a viable
farm unit to each of them. Women, conversely, may face social pressure to bear
many children so as to increase the number of future claimants to land resources
who belong to their lineage.
The implication derived from the above is that most rural
Africans attach high economic value to having large numbers of children. Larger
families appear to fare better economically than small families. Children
contribute labor in cropping, livestock tending, fishing, water and fuelwood
fetching, and child rearing. The available evidence, although imperfect,
suggests that high demand for children may be partly the result of the historic
abundance of land and the shortage of labor, combined with high infant, child,
and overall mortality rates and high food insecurity. Maintaining high fertility
is the rational response of people who seek to ensure adequate family labor and
the survival of children who would support them in old age. For men in
particular, polygyny makes good sense in this situation because it increases the
supply of female and child labor and improves the prospects for security in old
age. The widespread practice of payment of a bride price (instead of the woman's
family providing a dowry) reflects this reality where women are wanted for their
labor and their ability to beer many children. Early female marriage, common in
Africa, also increases the prospects for multiple childbirths.
Various other trends also tend to keep the TFRs high. As forest
resources, water availability, and soil fertility decline, farmers and
pastoralists obtain less product per hectare The main resource available to them
to increase production is family labor, which permits increasing the extent of
the land farmed. It also makes it easier to diversify the sources of family
income with more seasonal or full-time off-farm employment. Hence, agricultural
stagnation and environmental degradation, in resource poor situations
characteristic of most of SubSaharan Africa, provide an economic
incentiveand often a survival strategy to maintain large families.
These factors also provide an incentive to keep children out of school to work
on the parental farm or with the family's livestock.
This situation is exacerbated by the specific and important
responsibilities placed on women in most farming systems of SubSaharan Africa.
Women are often responsible for food cropping, and almost always for fuelwood
and water provision (Chapter 5). As soil fertility declines and distances to
fuelwood and water sources increase, many rural women are faced with the
situation that the only resource that can be increased to meet the increasing
need for labor is child labor. More labor substitutes for reduced soil fertility
and compensates for the greater difficulty in obtaining fuel and water. This
then completes a vicious circle in which population growth, combined with
traditional farming practices, contributes to environmental degradation, in turn
contributing to further agricultural stagnation and to the persistence of high
rates of population growth.
These hypotheses are consistent with statistical tests (see the
Appendix to Chapter 3) which show that, other things being equal, TFRs are
highest in those SSA countries that have the most cultivated land per capita.
Similarly, TFRs are highest in countries with the highest infant mortality
rates, lowest level of female education, lowest urbanization, and greatest
degree of land degradation. This suggests that demand for children as well as
TFRs will decline over timeeven without an active population
policyas population density on cultivated land increases, and if female
school enrollment rates rise, infant mortality declines, urbanization increases,
and environmental degradation is minimized.
However, changes in these determinants of the demand for
children are coming about only slowly. Analysis of available cross-country data
suggests a considerable degree of inertia in fertility rates as well as the
presence of many other factors that influence fertility rates but for which data
are not available. Cultural elements appear to be very important; Commenting on
the findings obtained from the analysis of the WFS data collected in the late
1970s and early 1980s, one of the program leaders stated that the onset of the
demographic transition "appears to be determined more by ill-understood cultural
factors than by any objectively ascertainable development indicators" (GilIe
1985:279). These cultural determinants are likely to change only slowly, even
though many of the factors that help shape culture are changing. Fertility rates
will decline, but only slowly, and only if infant mortality declines lines and
environmental degradation is arrested. But progress in these two critical areas
is occurring too slowly to compensate for the enormous difference between the
current rates of growth of population and of agricultural production.
Nonetheless, rising population pressure on cultivated land,
declining infant mortality rates and improvements in female education are
stimulating demand for family planning services. Much of this demand remains, at
present, unmet (Table
A-6).