Executive summary
0.1 Rising incomes, growing health consciousness, and
urbanization are among the major factors contributing to changing dietary
patterns, both in industrialized and developing countries. While there are
differences in the pace and specific features of these dietary changes, there
has been a common shift toward increased consumption of fresh and processed
fruits and vegetables, of protein-rich meats, fish, dairy products, and
vegetable oils, and of prepared 'convenience' foods. Compared with cereals and
other staple food products, these foods have relatively high unit values and
face relatively high income elasticities of demand.
0.2 Changing dietary patterns, together with technical advances
in food-related logistics and multilateral reductions in trade barriers, have
contributed to a rapid expansion in world trade in the above noted highvalue
foods (HVF) over the past quarter century. During the 1980s, a period in which
the aggregate value of world trade in cereals, sugar, and tropical beverage
crops actually declined, the above categories of HVF experienced average annual
growth rates in world trade ranging from 4% (e.g. fresh vegetables; fresh meat)
to more than 11% (e.g. dairy products; shell fish). World trade in HVF is now
considerable. In 1988/89, it totalled $144 billion, representing 5% of total
world commodity trade and a value equivalent to world trade in crude petroleum.
0.3 Developing countries have actively participated in this
international HVF trade, both as importers and exporters. In 1990, exports of
HVF by middle- and low-income countries totalled $52.5 billion. For comparison,
the aggregate exports of such countries for coffee, cocoa, tea, sugar, cotton,
and tobacco was only $26.3 billion-- roughly one-half. Over the past decade,
developing countries have outperformed industrialized countries in export growth
for several categories of HVF (e.g. fresh/processed fish, fresh/processed fruit,
oilseeds, and feedstuffs). Despite these patterns, most analyses of developing
country agro-industrial experience and agricultural trade problems and prospects
continue to focus on the traditional beverage and industrial crops.
0.4 In 1990, there were twenty-four middle- and low-income
countries whose HFV exports exceeded $500 million. The majority of such
countries are either Latin American (10) or Asian (8), with most of these
countries also being among the leading developing country exporters of
manufactured goods. Only a few African and Middle Eastern countries have
developed significant levels of HFV exports. Two Eastern European
countriesHungary and Poland-- are among the leaders as a result of their
significant exports of meat products and fresh and processed fruits and
vegetables.
0.5 Although many developing countries have developed some
exports of HVF, there is a relatively high level of concentration of this trade
among a few countries. For example, only four countries--Brazil, Argentina,
China, and Thailand-- account for 40% of the total HVF exports for all middle-
and low-income countries. Only ten countries account for two-thirds of the total
trade and twenty countries for 90%. Major cases of success in developing country
HVF exporting are thus less widespread than might be indicated by aggregated
data for export levels and growth.
0.6 This paper provides a synthesis of notable "success stories"
of demand-driven production, processing, and marketing of HVF among developing
countries. It examines in comparative perspective the development, organization,
and performance of entire commodity systems rather than the experience of
individual projects or companies. It focuses on cross-cutting issues and common
patterns rather than elaborating on the microeconomic and historical details of
individual cases. By identifying common technical, institutional, policy, and
other factors which have contributed to commodity system development and
international competitiveness, the paper seeks to contribute to the design of
improved strategies for supporting food market development and export
diversification in developing countries and in the formerly centrally-planned
economies.
0.7 A total of fifteen commodity system "success stories" from
nine countries were reviewed, drawing upon consultancy, academic, and
international agency studies, trade journals, USDA country and commodity
reports, and official and international agency production and trade data. Two
case studies benefitted from prior field work conducted by the author.
Abbreviated case studies (of 2 to 5 pages) are presented in an Appendix with the
main text providing a synthesis of the operating contexts, performance patterns,
and organizational features of the focal cases. Important cross-cutting issues
include: the respective roles of the public and private sectors, the importance
of foreign capital and technology, the institutional links between producers,
processor/exporters, and foreign market distributors, and the conjuncture of
market, technical, policy, and other factors which contributed to the export
booms experienced in these commodity systems.
0.8 The fifteen cases covered had aggregate export earnings of
$11 billion in 1988/89, representing more than 20% of total HFV exports by all
middle- and low-income countries. The nine countries included in the sample
together account for 50% of developing country HVF exports. The cases selected
cover a range of horticultural, fish, meat, and oilseed products and include
commodity systems whose 'take-off' or boom periods occurred in different
decades. Although the majority of cases experienced such export booms in the
1970s and/or 1980s, several of the commodity systems pre-date this period, with
two dating back to the 19th Century. The specific cases examined are:
(1) Mexican fresh tomatoes,
(2) Kenyan specialty and
'off-season' vegetables,
(3) Israeli fresh citrus,
(4-6) Chilean
temperate fruit, processed tomatoes, and fish products,
(7-8) Brazilian
frozen concentrated orange juice and soybean products,
(9-10) Argentine beef
and soybean products,
(11-13) Thai poultry, tuna, and shrimp,
(14)
Chinese shrimp, and
(15) Taiwanese high-value processed foods.
Economic and institutional issues in the marketing of high-value
foods
0.9 Consistent with recent work on agro-industrial development
(Austin (1992)), the paper argues that major problems in food marketing and the
range of institutional, infrastructural, and technological solutions to such
problems are best understood when examined from a commodity systems perspective.
This perspective emphasizes that modern food marketing is demand-driven, that
farm-level production and downstream marketing activities are highly
interdependent, and that such activities must therefore be coordinated, whether
through market, cooperative, or administrative means.
0.10 The paper identifies a series of intrinsic technical and
economic characteristics of food commodities/ raw materials, food production,
and marketing infrastructure and services which can lead commodity system
participants (e.g. farmers, processors, traders) to experience major problems
related to production and market risk, inadequate or asymmetric information,
logistical bottlenecks, and high transaction costs. Among the noted intrinsic
characteristics include: a) the bulkiness, perishability, and heterogeneity of
food commodities/raw materials, b) the yield uncertainty, seasonality, and
extended gestation periods associated with the production of many foods, and c)
the public good aspects, externalities and/or economies of scale associated with
many types of marketing-related infrastructure and marketing services.
0.11 The paper then examines a range of technical,
institutional, and other measures which can counter the incentive, risk,
transaction cost, and logistical problems raised by the intrinsic technical and
economic properties of food commodities, production, etc.. Many of these counter
measures are essentially market or quasi-market responses on the part of private
firms and individuals; others entail government interventions which stimulate,
re-direct, constrain, or supplement private activity.
0.12 Drawing from the industrial development literature, the
paper also examines the issue of commodity system competitiveness and its
contributing factors. From Porter (1990), it is noted that a commodity system
can achieve a competitive advantage either by 1) having lower costs of
production and delivery, or 2) differentiating its product(s) through its
quality or through accompanied technical or marketing services. A lower cost
structure allows a commodity system to underprice its competitors or obtain
higher returns when international prices are at or near the competitors' costs.
Product/service differentiation facilitates the attainment of premium prices
and/or the ability to fill profitable niches in the market.
0.13 Five sets of factors are discussed as being determinants of
commodity system competitiveness. These are: 1) the size and patterns of food
demand, 2) macroeconomic and sector policies, 3) natural resources and human
capital, 4) physical, technical, and social infrastructure, and 5)
micro-marketing and logistical activities and the coordination of production
with downstream requirements. The first and second of these factor sets
determine or strongly influence the incentives for specialized food production
and marketing activities. Factor sets (3) and (4) determine the capacity to
respond to these incentives, while factor set (5) determines the efficiency of
this response and the quality of the resultant product(s).
Synthesis of HVF Commodity Success Stories
0.14 Among the nine focal countries, only three--China,
Thailand, and Brazil-- have achieved levels of agricultural performance above
the norm for middle- and low-income countries over the 1965 - 1989 period. Over
much of this period, each of the other focal countries has experienced rates of
growth in agricultural GDP and total food production which trail aggregate
growth rates for middle- and low-income countries. However, in certain commodity
systems, including those examined in this paper, the focal countries have
experienced high rates of production and trade growth, either spanning several
decades or covering the past decade. Double-digit rates of growth in production
and/or trade have been experienced in one, two, or more decades for each of our
focal cases. The commodities in question have come to account for rising shares
of national food exports.
0.15 Most of the focal commodity systems experienced their
initial export booms during the 1970s or 1980s in response to favorable
international market opportunities. Some cases featured phenomenal export
growth, as in the growth of Brazil's soybean/soybean product exports from only
$71 million in 1970 to $2.2 billion in 1980, and the growth in Thailand's canned
tuna exports from zero in 1980 to over $500 million by the end of the decade.
Large increases in world market shares were recorded in several of the focal
cases. In such cases as Mexican tomatoes, Chilean temperate fruit, Thai tuna,
Chinese shrimp, Brazil FCOJ, and Brazilian and Argentine soybeans/soybean
products, the focal commodity systems are (among) the leaders of world trade.
0.16 In the majority of cases, the focal commodity systems have
(or had) a production cost advantage over major rivals due to a combination of
relatively low labor costs, low land costs, government-built or subsidized
infrastructure, and/or relatively high yields. These production cost advantages
have been at least partly off-set by higher processing, packaging, and/or
transport costs, especially in comparison with industrialized country
competitors.
0.17 In many of the focal commodity systems, either initially or
more recently, firms have sought to compete in international markets by
differentiating their products and/or marketing services. This has included
efforts to provide especially high-quality products, to supply products matching
special manufacturer requirements or consumer tastes, and/or to supply a broad
range of products. In several cases (including Thai poultry and shrimp, Chilean
fish products, and several areas of food processing in Taiwan (China)), firms
(or an entire industry) have made a successful transition from being low-cost,
low-price suppliers to suppliers of highquality, value-added products obtaining
premium prices. In the case of Taiwan (China), rising labor and other costs
rendered such product up-grading essential for industry survival.
0.18 Each of the focal commodity systems faced highly favorable
international market conditions during their initial export boom years and for
many years thereafter. Not only did income growth and changing life-styles
contribute to generally increasing demand, but several of our focal commodities
experienced sudden market undersupply periods ("market vacuums") lasting for
several years as a result of trade embargoes or climatic, political, or other
problems experienced by traditional suppliers. Furthermore, most of the
commodities covered in this study are foods about which industrialized country
consumers are well aware and for which market distribution channels pre-dated
the arrival of the focal country firms. Hence, market development costs were far
lower than they would be if an exotic product were being introduced.
0.19 Most of the focal commodity systems have also featured
favorable trends in domestic market demand. In more than half of the cases,
export development followed upon many years of domestic marketing experience,
during which infrastructure and institutions were built up. In these and in
several other cases, export booms were accompanied by a rapid growth in the
domestic market which provided an outlet for blemished or local grade produce,
an outlet for animal/fish parts or products which can not be profitably
exported, and an overall fall-back position in case of unforeseen barriers to
export. In several cases, levels of domestic per capita consumption are (among)
the highest in the world.
0.20 The paper provides a brief review of the macroeconomic
context in which commodity systems emerged and later developed. For only two of
the focal countries--Taiwan (China) and Thailand-- has the macroeconomic
environment been generally favorable for investment and export development over
most of the past quarter century. While China featured strong government
controls on investment and trade until the 1980s, each of the other focal
countries has experienced extended periods of currency overvaluation, high
inflation, and low growth and investment. Still, for many of the focal cases,
export booms took place just after or parallel with the adoption of
macroeconomic and trade reforms which improved incentives. The only exception to
this was with Argentine soybeans/soybean products, whose initial export boom (in
the early-tomid-1970s) accompanied the implementation of more stringent trade
controls and higher export taxes by a new administration.
0.21 In thirteen of the fifteen focal cases, the private sector
has played a dominant or exclusive role in commercial production, processing,
and marketing. This private sector has generally consisted of both local and
foreign/joint venture companies with the former continuing to account for the
majority of trade in all but one of the cases. A dominant or major commercial
role for government agencies has occurred only in the cases of Chinese shrimp
and Israeli citrus. In the former, state enterprises were instrumental in the
initial development of aquaculture and in the continued development of trade. In
the latter, an export monopoly marketing board replaced a formerly competitive
private and cooperative trade and retained its monopoly until 1991. In several
other cases, government agencies have undertaken some trade, either in
conjunction with domestic price support and stockholding programs or as part of
government to government international deals. The magnitude of such trade has
generally been quite small.
0.22 While state enterprises have played prominent commercial
roles in few of the focal cases, in virtually all cases governments have played
important facilitating roles. This has included the provision of social overhead
and marketing infrastructure (e.g. ports, railways, roads, cold stores,
auction/terminal markets), programs in agricultural and food technology research
and training, factory and/or product inspection and certification, and, in about
half of the cases, some form of market information scheme. In many cases,
governments have negotiated favorable terms for international market access and
offered some form of trade promotion assistance. Each of these common areas of
government involvement pertain to facilities or services which either have
public good properties or give rise to externalities.
0.23 In a majority of cases, government interventions have
extended beyond the above roles to include more active microeconomic
interventions. This has frequently involved one or more types of subsidy or
investment credit, although in the majority of cases such bonuses were available
to producers, processors, and traders of other commodities as well. Price
supports and/or price or quantity controls have been periodically applied in
many of the focal cases. Data available for several of the focal Latin American
case studies indicate that the aggregate effect of direct and indirect
government interventions has been one of net taxation, suggesting that levels of
production and trade would have been higher in the absence of interventions.
0.24 The paper examines organizational patterns in the focal
commodity systems, including competitive structures and institutional links
between producers, processors/exporters, and foreign market distributors. In the
vast majority of cases, while domestic marketing systems have remained
decentralized, export-oriented processing and trade has tended toward high rates
of concentration with between three and ten firms accounting for the bulk of
capacity and trade. In some cases, such concentration patterns have derived
primarily from economic factors (e.g. economies of scale, differential
capabilities and performance, etc.); in other cases, government interventions
have determined or directly contributed to such patterns. Concentrated (although
not monopolistic) trade structures have apparently facilitated improved quality
control, marketing logistics, and, in some cases, an ability to influence world
commodity prices.
0.25 Another common organizational pattern has been the
prominence of contract farming and/or vertical integration in the linkages
between farm-level production and downstream processing and trade. Open market
buying and selling of raw materials has become only a supplementary,
market-clearing mechanism in many of the focal commodity systems. In many cases,
the leading firms have developed their own programs of applied research,
extension, input delivery, and credit as a supplement or replacement for markets
and government programs for such services.
0.26 Contract-based or intra-firm trade have also been
significant features of the export operations in the majority of the focal
commodity systems. Such long-term marketing ties have helped to maintain market
access, lower logistical and transaction costs, and facilitate flows of
information and technologies which have enabled suppliers to better meet
changing consumer and buyer tastes and requirements.
0.27 Foreign capital, technology, training, and/or management
skills have played an important role in the development of most of the focal
commodity systems. In virtually all of the focal Latin American cases, credit
from foreign distributors or direct foreign investments in production and/or
processing/marketing facilities played a major role in initial subsector growth.
Similar agroclimatic conditions between the focal countries and parts of the
United States facilitated the transfer of crop varieties and of cultivation
techniques.
Lessons and Policy Implications
0.28 One of the lessons of the "success stories" experiences is
that agricultural export diversification by developing countries need not focus
on exotic tropical commodities and need not depend upon low labor costs for
international competitiveness. The collective experience suggests that
developing countries can compete against industrialized country suppliers in the
markets for a wide range of high-value and highvolume commodities on the bases
of both cost and quality. Although such quality-based competitiveness did not
occur overnight, with the liberal adoption/adaption of foreign technologies and
advice and with the buildup of local skills, infrastructure, research
capabilities, and experience, many of the focal commodity systems succeeded to
match or exceed competitive quality standards within a decade after initial
international market entry. A niche market strategy may well be necessary for
very small countries which lack the capacity the potential to serve mass-market
distribution systems. Larger middle- and low-income countries should aspire to
compete in larger, faster growing markets.
0.29 A second important lesson is that successful export
diversification often depends upon prior or parallel development of domestic
markets. None of the focal commodity systems has developed as an export-oriented
enclave and relatively few have relied upon export markets for the bulk or even
the majority of their sales. This complementarily between export and domestic
market development is much more important for high-value food commodities than
it is for many traditional developing country export crops (e.g. tropical
beverages, tobacco) given the limited domestic market for the latter. This
suggests that government and donor programs and other interventions geared
towards agricultural export diversification should not only seek to build upon
existing domestic marketing experience, but should also incorporate investment
and other components to support further domestic market development.
0.30 A third lesson is that governments and donors should
facilitate foreign and joint venture investments and international transfers of
production and processing technologies. This implies a streamlining of
procedures for foreign investment, and a reduction in tariff and non-tariff
barriers for the importation of planting materials, irrigation and processing
equipment, and other technology-embodied inputs into agribusiness operations.
0.31 A fourth lesson is that while favorable macroeconomic
conditions and policies have provided stimuli for new investments and expanded
trade for most of the focal commodity systems at certain points in time, much of
the initial supply response to favorable international market conditions and
most of the sustained production and trade expansion experienced in the focal
cases can be attributed to a combination of a) microeconomic developments (e.g.
joint ventures, vertical integration, investment incentive programs, etc.), and
b) investments in human capital and support structures (e.g. infrastructure,
research). This implies that efforts geared toward promoting agricultural export
diversification will need to extend beyond policy reform programs to include
human capital and brick and mortar investments as well as microeconomic
initiatives.
0.32 A final lesson is that both the public and private sectors
have important roles to play in the development of high-value food exports.
Among the prerequisites for profitable and sustainable trade are the
availability of transport and telecommunications facilities and the maintenance
of law and order. These goods and services are normally provided by the public
sector. In the focal commodity systems, the role of the public sector has
extended beyond these basic public goods and services. Probably the most
important means of government support has come through the development of public
'knowledge systems', comprising research, training, extension, quality control,
and market information services. While such public services were commonly
supplemented (or replaced) by private initiative owe the commodity systems
reached relatively advanced levels of development, these public services were
generally crucial in the initial development or adoption of production and
processing technologies and in the subsequent improvements in productivity and
quality which enabled the participating firms to successfully compete in
international markets. In many of the focal cases, government agencies have also
conducted export promotion activities, although these were generally less
important than efforts to negotiate favorable or at least equitable access to
important international markets.
0.33 The collective experience of the focal commodity systems
leads to the conclusion that the commercial production, processing, and
marketing of high-value foods should be left to the private sector. While in
several of the focal cases public enterprises have directly participated in
trade, most such enterprises have adopted a production push- rather than
market-orientation, have been averse to risk-taking, and have been operationally
inflexible. Though proving adept at selling commodities to undersupplied
markets, such state enterprises were not effective in marketing differentiated
products in competitive markets. In contrast, the private sector (including
trading cooperatives) has demonstrated far greater ability to anticipate,
respond to, or cultivate changes in market demand and service requirements and
has been far more innovative in developing products and inter-organizational
linkages to facilitate expanded trade. These differential properties of public
and private trading enterprises are particularly important in the development of
high-value food exports given the importance of service, quality, and product
form differentiation in major international markets for these
goods.