Cover Image
close this bookEnergy as an Instrument for Socio-economic Development (UNDP, 1995, 114 p.)
close this folderPART 3: REMOVING THE OBSTACLES LARGE-SCALE APPROACH
View the document9. Biomass Plantation Energy Systems and Sustainable Development
View the document10. Converting Biomass to Liquid Fuels: Making Ethanol from Sugar Cane in Brazil

9. Biomass Plantation Energy Systems and Sustainable Development

ERIC D. LARSON AND ROBERT H. WILLIAMS1

Biomass today accounts for over one third of all energy used in developing countries (see Figure 9.1). It has been called "the poor man's oil" because its direct use by combustion for domestic cooking and heating ranks it at the bottom of the ladder of preferred energy carriers.2 Existing biomass-using technologies are relatively inefficient; thus, biomass provides less energy service than the proportion of total energy it represents, and women and children in rural areas spend considerable time collecting daily fuelwood needs. Biomass energy use today also contributes to indoor air pollution and associated negative health impacts. (Editor's Note; see chapters 2 and 5 in this volume.) Furthermore, most biomass energy today comes from natural forests, contributing to deforestation in some countries.

Biomass has the potential to provide a much higher level of energy services in developing countries, in environmentally friendly ways, if the production and conversion of biomass is modernized.3 A recent assessment of the potential for renewable energy, prepared as input for the U.N. Conference on Environment and Development (UNCED), found that sustainable biomass energy systems could be the largest single contributor to global energy supply; the study found that under a "Renewables-Intensive Global Energy Scenario" (RIGES), biomass could provide as much as 35 per cent of the total demand for primary energy in 2050 (see Figure 9.2a).4 A "sustained growth scenario" developed by the Shell International Petroleum Company's Group Planning Division found biomass' potential contribution to total energy supplies in 2050 to be similar (about 210 EJ - one Exajoule is 1018 joules) (see Figure 9.2b).5

Such visions of large contributions by biomass to global energy supply are plausible because ongoing technological advances offer the promise of being able to turn biomass into more desirable forms of energy (such as electricity and liquid and gaseous fuels) in ways that are both environmentally friendly and economically competitive with fossil fuel alternatives. These technological advances are of comparable significance to the fundamental technological developments (steam turbines and internal combustion engines) that were largely responsible for the expansive growth in global fossil fuel use that began late in the nineteenth century.

In the RIGES, the majority of biomass energy supplies come from high-yielding energy plantations covering some 430 million hectares worldwide, or an area equivalent to roughly one fourth the area currently used for agriculture worldwide. Africa and Latin America would be the two largest biomass producing regions (Table 9.1).


Figure 9.1 - Estimated Energy Use Distribution in Developing Countries, Industrial Countries, and the World, 1987

Source: Reprinted, with permission, from D.O. Hall, F. Rosillo-Calle, R.H. Williams, and J. Woods, "Biomass for Energy: Supply Prospects," Renewable Energy: Sources of Fuels and Electricity, p. 595. 1993. Published by Island Press, Washington, DC, and Covelo, California.


Figure 9.2 - Two Biomass-Intensive Future Global Energy Scenarios

Sources: Part A is the renewables-intensive global energy scenario (RIGES) of T.B. Johansson, H. Kelly, A.K.N. Reddy, and R.H. Williams, "Renewable Fuels and Electricity for a Growing World Economy: Defining and Achieving the Potential," Chapter 1, pp. 1-71, and "A Renewables-Intensive Global Energy Scenario," Appendix to Chapter 1, pp. 1071-1142, in T.B. Johansson et al. (eds.), Renewable Energy: Sources for Fuels and Electricity (Washington: Island Press, 1993).; the historical data are from J. Davis, "Energy for Planet Earth," Scientific American (September 1990). Part B is the "Sustained Growth Scenario" developed by the Shell International Petroleum Company's Group Planning Division in P. Kassler, Energy for Development, Selected Paper (London: Shell International Petroleum Company, Shell Centre, August 1994).

Note that in both scenarios, the total contribution of biomass in 2050 is approximately 210 EJ.

The RIGES envisions that initial major markets for commercial (monetized) biomass would be primarily for electric power generation since advanced technologies for power generation from biomass at scales of 20 to 150 MWe (gasifier/gas turbine systems) will be commercially available by the year 2000; these can be expected to be competitive with new and much larger coal-fired power plants and, in some cases, with hydroelectricity.7

The RIGES further envisions that as oil and natural gas prices rise, domestic and export markets for transportation fuels (e.g., methanol and hydrogen) will provide further opportunities for continued rapid growth of biomass energy industries. Under this scenario, developing countries (especially in Latin America and Africa), thus, have rural-based domestic sources of commercial fuels, and thereby, new opportunities for rural development. Moreover, energy markets for biomass would provide economic incentives for afforestation of degraded and marginal lands and, in the longer term, foreign exchange earnings.

This paper examines potential land availability for a biomass-intensive energy future, some of the economic and social implications of such a future for rural development of developing countries, and some key environmental issues associated with extensive biomass energy production.

Table 9.1 - Total Biomass Supplies for Energy (EJ/year) for the Renewables-Intensive Global Energy Supply Scenario (RIGES)

REGION

YEAR 2025

YEAR 2050


Forests

Residues

Energy Crops

TOTAL

Forests

Residues

Energy Crops

TOTAL

Africa

2.43

6.81

18.94

28.18

2.43

9.38

31.81

43.62

Latin America

1.59

10.92

32.30

44.81

1.59

13.59

49.60

64.78

S&E Asia

3.13

13.61

-

16.74

3.13

20.42

-

23.55

CP Asia

1.21

3.85

5.00

10.06

1.21

4.16

15.00

20.37

Japan

-

0.89

-

0.89

-

0.95

-

0.95

Australia/NZ

0.02

1.14

-

1.16

0.02

1.39

-

1.41

USA

0.61

5.86

9.60

16.07

0.61

5.68

9.60

15.89

Canada

0.04

1.43

1.20

2.67

0.04

1.42

1.20

2.66

OECD Europe

0.31

4.85

9.00

14.16

0.31

4.86

9.00

14.17

Former CP Europe

0.58

5.28

4.00

9.86

0.58

5.68

12.00

18.26

Middle East

0.02

0.18

-

0.20

0.02

0.23

-

0.25

TOTAL

9.94

54.82

80.04

144.80

9.94

67.76

128.21

205.91

Source: T.B. Johansson, H. Kelly, A.K.N. Reddy, and R.H. Williams, "Renewable Fuels and Electricity for a Growing World Economy: Defining and Achieving the Potential," Chapter 1, pp. 1-71, and "A Renewables-Intensive Global Energy Scenario, "Appendix to Chapter 1,pp. 1071-1142, in T.B. Johansson et al. (eds.), Renewable Energy: Sources for Fuels and Electricity (Washington: Island Press, 1993).

Potential Land Availability for Biomass Energy

Because populations are growing, an important question is whether there are sufficient land resources to both feed future populations and sustain the magnitude of biomass energy development implied in the RIGES and the Shell scenario.

USING DEGRADED LANDS FOR BIOMASS ENERGY

To help insure a minimum of competition between agriculture and energy production, a number of analysts have proposed that developing countries target degraded lands for energy production.8 Grainger and Oldeman et al. have estimated that developing countries have over 2,000 million hectares of degraded lands, and Grainger estimates that some 621 million of these are suitable for reforestation.9 This is consistent with estimates that previously forested area suitable for reforestation amounts to 500 million hectares, with an additional 365 million hectares available from land in the fallow phase of shifting cultivation.10

Worldwide interest in restoring tropical degraded lands is growing, as indicated by the ambitious goal of a global net afforestation rate of 12 million hectares per year by 2000, set in 1989 at the Ministerial Conference on Atmospheric Pollution and Climate Change.11 This is comparable to the rate at which biomass energy plantations would have to be established in the first quarter of the twenty-first century for Africa, Latin America, and centrally planned Asia to meet the goals envisaged in the RIGES.

Energy industries might provide the capital needed to finance land restoration activities since advanced biomass conversion technologies like gasifier/gas turbine systems are expected to be highly economically attractive. In principle, energy industries would have an incentive to restore lands in sustainable ways because they would require secure supplies of biomass feedstocks throughout the lifetimes (twenty years or more) of their capital-intensive investments in energy conversion facilities. Such supply security could be assured only if the plantations were managed sustainably.

The main technical challenge is to find a sequence of plantings that can restore ground temperatures, organic and nutrient content, moisture levels, and other soil conditions to a point where crop yields are high and sustainable. It appears feasible to overcome this challenge.12 Other difficulties that must be surmounted reflect general conditions in many developing regions, for example, complex or disputed land ownership, lack of roads or other means to transport biomass to processing facilities and biofuels to markets, and the fact that growers in poor areas cannot wait the three to eight years that is typically required for cash returns on short-rotation tree crops. Despite these technical, socio-economic, political, and other difficulties, however, proof of the potential for growing energy crops on degraded lands can be found in the many successful energy plantations that already exist in developing countries.13

Nevertheless, intensive research, development, and implementation programmes are needed to accelerate the rate of plantation development. Such programmes should lead to the development of region-specific restoration plans that take into account local bioclimatic and socio-economic conditions. Restoration activities involving both outside experts and local farmers should be investigated. Also, restoration plans that can lead to commercial energy crops should be demonstrated. Such demonstrations might be conducted as joint ventures among local agricultural producers and equipment supply firms, local and multinational energy companies, and local and international organizations interested in land restoration.

FOOD VERSUS FUEL

The use of degraded lands offers an important opportunity for growing biomass energy crops, but other possibilities should be examined as well. This, in turn, requires careful examination of the potential land requirements for agriculture.

Waggoner argues that a world with twice the present population could be fed with no increase in cropland, largely because of expected continuing increases in yields.14 A cursory examination of historical trends in grain yields suggests this may be reasonable. Worldwide average grain yields have been increasing at an average linear rate of 40 kilograms per hectare per year since 1960 (see Figure 9.3). To provide constant per capita levels of grain using the same amount of land as at present, as suggested by Waggoner, would require an average global increase in yields from 2.6 metric tonnes per hectare per year in 199315 to 4.5 tonnes per hectare per year in 2050 and 5.2 in 2100.16 The implied linear growth rate is 33 kg/ha/yr from 1993 to 2050, and 14 kg/ha/yr from 2050 to 2100, both slower than the average growth rate of 40 kg/ha/yr from 1960 to the early 1990s. The target yield of 5.2 tonnes per hectare in 2100 is about 94 per cent of the 1993 U.S. yield, 30 per cent higher than China's 1993 average, and 18 per cent above the 1993 South Korean yield.


Figure 9.3 - Average Cereal Yields for the World, the United States, Brazil, Asia, and Africa, 1960-1990

Note: Over the period 1972 to 1990, yields increased a total of 28% in Africa, 77% in Asia, 49% in Brazil, and 33% in the United States.

Sources: Country and regional data are Food and Agriculture Organization data cited in C.I. Marrison and E.D. Larson, "A Preliminary Estimate of the Biomass Energy Production Potential in Africa for 2025," Center for Energy and Environmental Studies, Princeton University, Princeton, New Jersey, March 23, 1995. World data are from U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA), "Production, Supply, and Distribution Database" (diskette), Economic Research Service, USDA, Washington (September 1994).

While such a global analysis is encouraging, it may prove difficult in practice to maintain agricultural land use at present levels on a regional or sub-regional basis. In a more detailed analysis aimed at a preliminary country-level quantification of potential biomass energy production, Marrison and Larson estimate the land availability and associated bioenergy production potential for fifty African countries in the year 2025. 17 Their analysis assumes that food crop yields in Africa grow at the same linear rate between 1990 and 2025 as average cereal-crop yields grew there from 1972 to 1990 (13.8 kg/ha/year). Average crop yields in 2025 would then still be below Brazil's 1990 level, and far below the 1990 U.S. level (see Figure 9.3).

Marrison and Larson use U.N. baseline population projections, which suggest that Africa's population in 2025 will be 2.5 times the 1990 level. They assume that food imports do not increase beyond the absolute 1990 levels, and that per capita calorie supplies grow to correct current undernourishment. With these assumptions, the cropland requirements for Africa in 2025 will be 451 million hectares, or 2.4 times the present cropland area. Marrison and Larson assume that new cropland would be established on land that is presently not cropland, not natural forest, and not wilderness (including desert areas). After meeting cropland needs, any remaining land that is not cropland, forest, or wilderness is assumed to be available for other uses, including biomass energy production. There will be a variety of competing uses for this available area that must be examined on a region-by-region basis when considering the establishment of biomass plantations.

Marrison and Larson project biomass energy crop yields on the potentially available land on the basis of annual nationally averaged precipitation and a yield-precipitation correlation for modern commercial eucalyptus plantations in Brazil. Figure 9.4 shows the percentage of non-crop, non-forest, non-wilderness area in 2025 that would be needed in Africa to produce 18.9 EJ of biomass energy in 2025 - the amount specified by the RIGES for Africa in Table 9.1. The percentage of available land required in each country producing biomass is shown as a function of the bioenergy plantation yield below which, biomass production is assumed to be uneconomic, i.e. the cut-off yield. Only 15 per cent (or 38.7 million hectares) of non-crop, non-forest, non-wilderness land in the producing countries (i.e., those with average yield higher than the cut-off level) would be needed to meet the RIGES target, if a cut-oft yield of 10 dry tonnes per hectare per year is assumed.

Marrison and Larson's analysis suggests that land resources are sufficient to support a biomass-intensive energy future in Africa without compromising food production needs. Subsequent analysis suggests similar conclusions for Latin America and Asia.18 That Asia could become a major bioenergy producer without compromising food production needs is surprising. It results form the high rate of growth in crop yields between 1972 and 1990 (see Figure 9.3). Marrison and Larson assume that yields continue increasing at the same linear rate (65 kg/ha/year for grains) from 1990 to 2025. With this assumption, crop yields in 2025 in Asia (5.4 t/ha/yr for cereals) are about the same as in the United States in 1993 (5.5 t/ha/yr). Thus, despite growing populations, increased crop yields mean that the land needed for agriculture in Asia in 2025 is the same as in 1990, which leaves some 1,300 million hectares of available land for other uses. An independent and more detailed analysis focusing on India (see next section) appears to support Marrison and Larson's conclusion. Nevertheless, because it is contrary to conventional thinking about land use constraints in Asia, more detailed country-level assessments are warranted.


Figure 9.4 - Land Area Required for Biomass Production in Africa as a Function of Cat-off Yield

Note: The cut-off yield is the yield below which it is assumed that biomass production would not be economically viable. This figure shows the percentage of non-crop, non-wilderness, non-forest land that would be needed in Africa in 2025 to produce a continent total of 18.9 EJ of biomass energy. The percentage of land required in each country that produces biomass goes up with increased "cutoff" yield because the total number of countries in Africa with yields above the cut-off yield drops with increasing cut-off yield.

Source: C.I. Marrison and E.D. Larson, "A Preliminary Estimate of the Biomass Energy Production Potential in Africa for 2025," Center for Energy and Environmental Studies, Princeton University, Princeton, New Jersey, March 23, 1995.

FEASIBILITY OF PLANTATION BIOENERGY PRODUCTION: NORTHEAST BRAZIL AND INDIA

The preceding section suggests that land resources are sufficient to support a significant biomass energy industry globally. However, detailed country and sub-country assessments are needed to determine the feasibility of implementing biomass plantation energy systems on an extensive basis. Two studies are reviewed here; one for northeast Brazil, a region with high per capita land availability, and one for India, a country with low per capita land availability.

Brazil. The nine states comprising the northeast region of Brazil account for 18 per cent of Brazil's land area, or nearly 10 per cent of South America. The northeast region has the lowest population density among the three most populated regions in Brazil. The only significant conventional energy resource in the region is hydroelectric power, the full economic potential of which will have been tapped by the end of the decade.

Given the high per capita land availability and the looming shortage of conventional energy sources, the utility responsible for electricity in northeast Brazil (Companhia Hidroeletrica do Sao Francisco - CHESF) began to examine the region's potential for biomass energy production over a decade ago.19 The CHESF studies mapped key physical aspects of the region (soil type and quality, rainfall, topography, elevation, etc.) to define five bioclimatic regions. For each of these, CHESF estimated the potential yields and costs of producing biomass based on experience with industrial eucalyptus plantations in other regions of Brazil. The CHESF studies took account of potential competition for land, and considered for biomass energy production only land that was judged suboptimal for most other uses, including agriculture.

The CHESF study estimated the land area potentially available for biomass plantations to be some 50 million hectares, or one third of the region (see Figure 9.5). Biomass yields were estimated to range from less than 3 dry tonnes per hectare per year on the worst lands to over 20 t/ha/yr on the best sites, with 12.5 t/ha/yr the average yield. The total potential biomass production on 50 million hectares in the northeast region is estimated to be some 12.6 EJ per year.20 By comparison, total primary energy use in the northeast in 1990 was only about 1.1 EJ.

That the biomass energy production potential of the region is so large is surprising because a large part of the region is considered semi-arid. Furthermore, roughly half the area identified by CHESF as suitable for plantations is characterized as having soil that is being degraded to some extent by wind erosion, water erosion, or chemical deterioration.21 A smaller percentage of area has also been characterized as susceptible to desertification, based on physical characteristics (soils, water resources, etc.), social conditions (e.g., land ownership structure), economic criteria (e.g., present use of land), and other indicators.22

Given the encouraging analysis of the biomass energy production potential in northeast Brazil, CHESF is now developing plans for implementing a biomass-electricity generating programme. Some potential social implications of such a programme are discussed below.

India. Recent analysis suggests that India, a country with a population density sixteen times greater than that for Brazil, may also have substantial potential for establishing biomass-plantation energy industries.

Ravindranath and Hall observe that total area under crops in India was roughly the same in 1990 (around 125 million hectares) as it was twenty years earlier, despite population growth averaging about 2.4 per cent per year during these two decades.23 (Cultivable non-cropland has also remained stable at about 40 million hectares.) In looking to future land requirements for agriculture, Ravindranath and Hall note that the average yield of India's most important crop, rice, is 1.7 tonnes per hectare per year, or about one half the Asian average, one third the yield in China and Japan, and one fifth the yield in South Korea. On the other hand, in some states in India (Tamil Nadu and Punjab), the rice yield is double the Indian average.

From these data and an analysis of the barriers to increasing crop yields and intensities (i.e., cultivation of at least two crops per year through irrigation), Ravindranath and Hall conclude that the prospects for doubling or tripling average annual yields in India are good. Thus, food production might be doubled or tripled without increasing cropped area, leaving substantial amounts of land for other uses.

Ravindranath and Hall propose using degraded lands in India for biomass energy production. They cite three estimates of degraded land area in India that range from 66 to 106 million hectares. (Total land area is about 300 million hectares.) Excluding degraded land presently under cultivation reduces these estimates to a range of 61 to 71 million hectares.

This land area can be put in perspective by considering its biomass energy production potential relative to present energy use in India. Assuming an average biomass yield of 10 dry tonnes per hectare per year (and a biomass energy content of 20 GJ/dry tonne - one GJ is 109 joules), 65 million hectares would produce 13 EJ of energy. India's total primary energy consumption in 1991 was under 11 EJ (26 per cent of which was in the form of biomass).24


Figure 9.5 - Land Potentially Available for Growing Biomass in Northeast Brazil

Note: The shaded areas on the large map are identified by CHESF as available and suitable for establishing biomass energy plantations in Northeast Brazil; they amount to approximately 50 million hectares. The inset positions the northeast region of Brazil within South America.

Source: A.E. Carpentieri, E.D. Larson, and J. Woods, "Future Biomass-Based Electricity Supply in Northeast Brazil," Biomass and Bioenergy 4(3) (1993), pp. 149-73.

Potential Role of Biomass Plantation Energy Systems in Promoting Sustainable Development

What roles could large-scale biomass plantation energy systems play in promoting sustainable development? The case of biomass electric power generation, the likely initial major market for new biomass energy supplies, is considered here as a concrete example.

LOWER ENERGY COSTS

In order to succeed, biomass power systems must be economically competitive with conventional fossil fuel alternatives. Since plantation-grown biomass is more costly than traditional residue biomass sources, the technologies used to convert the biomass into electricity must be more efficient and/or lower in capital cost than traditional biomass-electric technologies, which today typically use residues as fuel. (Traditional biomass-electric technologies would not be competitive with conventional energy sources when more costly plantation biomass is the fuel.) At a scale of 20 to 150 MWe, biomass-gasifier/gas turbine (BIG/GT) systems that will be commercialized by the turn of the century promise efficiencies that are roughly double those for traditional (steam-turbine) biomass power systems; moreover, they would substantially lower capital costs.25 BIG/GT technology should make it possible to deliver electricity to consumers from biomass-plantation energy systems at costs that are competitive with electricity from new coal-fired steam-electric plants. BIG/GT electricity is also likely to be able to compete with hydroelectric power in some situations.26

MAGNET FOR RURAL ECONOMIC ACTIVITY AND EMPLOYMENT GENERATION

In part, because of the availability of low-cost electricity, rural industrial-scale biomass energy systems might act as magnets for a variety of income-generating activities, leading to the creation of employment that could help stem urban migration.

The most direct income-generating activity would be managing the plantations. In regions where climate is especially suitable for biomass growth and labour costs are relatively low, such as in parts of Brazil, biomass production costs from plantations are less than US$2/GJ.27 If biomass is sold at $2/GJ, and yields are 10 to 15 dry tonnes per hectare per year, a plantation could generate gross revenues of $400 to $600 per hectare. This is comparable to the revenues generated from soybean production in Brazil today.28 Yet the cost of inputs (such as fertilizer and herbicides) for biomass energy production (especially for woody crops with 3 to 8 year rotations) are likely to be substantially lower than those for an annual crop like soybeans (see Table 9.2). Moreover, unlike Brazilian soybeans, which are largely exported, biomass would be used locally to generate electricity, which, in turn, could be consumed by additional income-generating industries within the legion.29

Carpentieri et al. estimate that large-area (contiguous tens of thousands of hectares) commercial plantations in Brazil generate 1.9 to 3.6 direct jobs per square kilometre. While this level of employment is relatively modest, it could be important locally. Furthermore, the availability of low-cost biopower could attract other employment-generating activities to the area. Energy-intensive industries, with their well paying jobs, might be especially attracted.

Table 9.2 - Typical Fertilizer and Herbicide Application Rates and Soil Erosion Rates for Selected Food and Energy Crop Production Systems in the United States

Cropping System

N-P-K. Application Rates (kg/ha/year)

Herbicide Application Rates (kg/ha/year)

Soil Erosion Rates (tonnes/ha/yr)

Annual Crops




Corn

135-60-80

3.06

21.81

Soybeans

20b5-70

1.83

40.9a

Perennial Energy Crops




Herbaceous

50a-60-60

0.25

0.2

Short-rotation woody

60c-15-15

0.39

2.0

a Based on data collected in the early 1980s. New tillage practices used today may lower these values

b The nitrogen input is inherently low for soybeans, a nitrogen-fixing crop.

c Not including nitrogen-fixing species.

Source: W.G. Hohenstein and L.L. Wright, "Biomass Energy Production in the United States: An Overview," Biomass and Bioenergy (1994), pp. 161-73.

One concern with such a rural industrialization strategy is that it may first require a sufficient amount of already existing electricity-consuming industrial activity to justify building any power plant. While this may be desirable, it is not essential. Initially, if there is insufficient local demand to utilize all the electricity being generated, the excess could be transported by wire to urban centers (as hydroelectricity is transported from remote sites in many countries today). Although this electricity would not be as cheap as that made available near the plant site, the extra electric transmission costs should not be prohibitive; transmission lines would tend be operated at high capacity factors, thus, reducing unit costs. (This is in contrast to the opposite situation in which centralized power generation near urban centers provides electricity for rural consumers; in this case, the lines are often poorly utilized because of sporadic demand patterns of rural electricity consumers.)

SMALL-SCALE BIOMASS PRODUCTION: THE FARM FORESTRY ALTERNATIVE

It is often assumed that contiguous, large-area plantations are required: a) to take advantage of economies of scale that can make biopower competitive, and b) to make a large contribution to global energy supply, such as those envisaged in the RIGES. However, large plantations may not be necessary for biomass to play major roles in the energy economy. An alternative small-scale biomass supply system - farm forestry - shows great promise and is increasingly being implemented in Brazil.30 Similar activities have been reported elsewhere.

In a typical farm-forestry programme in Brazil, a forestry company provides the material inputs and technical know-how for establishing trees on a farmer's land (1 to 50 hectares of trees per farm) and contracts with the farmer to buy some or all of the first harvest for an agreed upon price that incorporates repayment for the initial inputs and services. The inputs include saplings (usually some species of eucalyptus), fertilizers (applied at planting), herbicides (applied at some point after planting), and pesticides. The company samples the farmer's soil and provides fertilizers and species "tuned" to that soil.

Because of the sophisticated material inputs and the careful tending provided by the farmer, the biomass yields reported from small-farm plantings are not much below those reported for large-scale plantations owned and operated by forestry companies, and yields can be expected to increase as both farmers and their contracting companies learn improved methods and approaches (most programmes in Brazil started less than a decade ago). Moreover, any yield reductions are often offset by substantially lower costs to companies for establishing farm forests. Limited survey data indicate that the per hectare cost for farmer-contracted land ranges from 2 per cent to 42 per cent of the cost for company-owned land (see Table 9.3). The limited data suggest that delivered costs for biomass do not differ much between farm-forests and large-scale plantations.

Farm forestry is growing rapidly in Brazil, with encouragement from the private sector; from federal, state and local governments; and from farmers. Several hundred thousand hectares have been established without fanfare in less than a decade. This compares favourably with the estimated 6 to 7 million hectares of large-scale plantations established in Brazil since the 1960s. Farmer-owned plantations account for as much as 20 per cent of some forestry companies' total planted area (Table 9.3), and some companies have a goal of raising this fraction to 50 per cent or more.


Table 9.3 - Some Corporate Farmer Forestry Programmes in Brazil (based on information provided by individual companies)

Company

Aracruz

Champion

Cenibra

Riocell

Pains

Ripasa

Inpacel

Bahia Sul

Location (state)

EspiritoSanto

SaoPaulo

Minas Gerais

R. Grande do Sul

Minas Gerais

Sao Paulo

Parana

Bahia, E. Santo

Company-Owned Land









Total area (hectares)

200,000

n.a.

156,194

71,751

85,073

69,942

47,874

115,138

Area planted (hectares)

131,000

n.a.

87,935

52,487

51,467

50,365

25,768

66,902

Average establishment cost for new plantings2 ($/ha)

1,250

n.a.

1,670

960

n.a.

917

712

427

Average productivity of planted area (dry tonnes/ha/year)3

22.34

n.a.

17.8d

19.2d

n.a.

17.3d

19.85

21.8d

Average delivered cost of wood ($/dry tonne)6

39

n.a.

48

30

n.a.

n.a.

22

16

Farmer-Forestry Program









Year programme was started

1989

1960

1985

1989

1988

1991

1991

1992

Total number of farmers

2000

328

500

3098

314

85

110

16

Average total farm size (ha)

n.a.

n.a.

100

16

63

90

n.a.

300

Primary activity of farm

n.a.

cattle, corn, coffee, citrus

cattle

n.a.

n.a.

cattle

cattle, crops

cattle

Total area contracted for trees (ha)

30,000

13,000

8,500

4,985

2,4317

2,425

1,575

850

Average per-farm area planted with trees (ha)

15

40

17

1.6

7.7

29

14

53

Average productivity of planted area (dry tonnes/ha/year)

n.a.

15d

12.7d

15d

n.a.

15.8d

n.a.

n.a.

Average establishment cost to company ($/ha)

n.a.

430

240

23

n.a.

130

266

180

Average delivered cost of wood to company ($/dry tonne)e

n.a.

16

42

n.a.

n.a.

n.a.

n.a.

n.a.

Per cent of farms intending to commit total area to trees

n.a.

8

27

0

n.a.

6

2

0

1 Based on data collected in the early 1980s. New tillage practices used today may lower these values.

2 Includes land rent, sapling production, land preparation, planting, fertilizers, herbicides.

3 Yield data were originally provided in solid cubic meters. Typical species of eucalyptus in Brazil have a density of about 0.5 dry tonnes per solid cubic meter.

4 Includes only stem wood with diameter 7 cm or larger.

5 Starring from the total yield at harvest (in solid m3/ha) provided by the company, this has been calculated assuming a 6-year rotation and a wood density of 0.5 dry tonnes/m3.

6 Calculated from costs in $/solid m3, assuming a wood density of 0.5 dry tonnes per cubic meter.

7 Pains has a goal of contracting over 56,000 hectares under their farmer forestry programme, which would involve some 4,000 farmers.

Source: E.D. Larson, L.C.E. Rodriguez, and T.R. de Azevedo, "Farm Forestry in Brazil," presented at BioResources '94: Biomass Resources, A Means to Sustainable Development, Bangalore, India, 3-7 October, 1994.

Three recent developments are spurring the growth in farm forestry: 1) the federal tax incentives introduced in 1966 in Brazil to encourage tree planting were eliminated in 1988, making it much less attractive for forestry companies to expand their own plantation areas; 2) in regions where natural forests were being cut for wood (especially the states of Minas Gerais and Sao Paulo), natural forests within reasonable transportation distances have essentially been completely cut, with insufficient replanting to meet local needs; and 3) objections of environmentalists and others (largely on aesthetic grounds) to "overplanting" of trees have discouraged expansion of large tracts of company-owned plantations. (In the state of Espirito Santo, for example, Aracruz Florestal, a private company, is now prohibited by law from purchasing additional land for eucalyptus planting.)

The overall result of the small-farm forestry programmes has been minimal changes in land ownership and use patterns, while local wood supplies at reasonable costs have increased, and farmers (including formerly subsistence farmers) have gained a revenue source.

TAX BASE TO HELP FINANCE RURAL INFRASTRUCTURE DEVELOPMENT

Private biopower systems in rural areas could provide a substantial tax base for supporting rural infrastructure development, if the tax is structured to use at least most of the revenues this way, rather than diverting them to the urban sector.31 Tax revenues could help finance a wide range of infrastructure, including that needed to attract energy-using industries and to provide such public services as schools, hospitals, etc. As biopower plants attract power-consuming firms to rural areas, these firms would further add to the rural tax base.

In many developing countries, privatizing power generation would lead to higher electricity prices. At present, most electric utilities are publicly owned, and electricity prices are often kept below economically efficient long-run marginal cost levels on the assumption that low electricity prices are needed to stimulate development. As a result, revenues typically are insufficient to provide the capital needed for financing new power plant construction.32 Privatizing power generation and opening it up to independent power producers would overcome this problem, and the resulting competition would keep electricity prices in line with long-run marginal costs.

Box 9.1

Taxing Rural Industries: An Illustration of the Potential

There are a variety of approaches that could be considered for taxing rural industries to pay for infrastructure development. Without passing judgement on the relative merits of one taxation instrument over another, consider the following illustration of the potential revenue base that might be generated from a taxation strategy.

In the United States, property taxes on businesses and homes are levied to support much local infrastructure building. A property tax levied on a rapidly-growing, capital-intensive industry, such as the electric power industry, could provide an enormous tax revenue base. To illustrate this, suppose that a 1.5 per cent property tax were levied on biopower production facilities. (A 1.5 per cent per year tax on the installed capital cost is a typical rate for investor-owned power plants in the United States.) Such a tax applied to a first-generation 26 MWe BIG/GT power plant would account for only 6 per cent of the busbar cost (see Table 9.4), but the tax revenues would mount to $0.5 million per year or $15 million over the 30-year life of the plant.

Consider the implications of this calculation for a particular developing country, say India. In the mid-1980s, only about one sixth of electricity generated was provided to rural areas of India, even though nearly three-fourths of the population is rural. Suppose that a concentrated effort were made on the part of policy-makers to accelerate rural industrialization and that:

· for the country as a whole, installed electrical generating capacity grows 5 per cent per year;

· one-third of all new electrical generating capacity is sited in rural areas;

· the average installed cost for new generating capacity is $1300/kWe (the estimated cost for first-generation, mass-produced BIG/GT systems - see Table 9.4); and

· all rural power is provided by private power producers, who pay annual property taxes equal to 1.5 per cent of the installed capital cost.

Assuming an estimated installed generating capacity in India of 100 GW in 1994, then over the 30-year lives of all the power plants installed in a single year at the time this new policy is adopted, property tax revenues would amount to about $1 billion per year:

(30-year plant life) × (0.015/year) × ($1300/kWe) × (1/3) × (0.05/year) × (100,000,000 kWe) @ $109/year.

Electricity so produced could be a powerful instrument for rural development if taxation instruments are used creatively. The methods of taxation should reflect cultural preferences, as well as considerations of economic and administrative efficiency. Taxes on capital, for example, might be especially effective with a capital-intensive industry like power generation (see Box 9.1).

Tax revenues could be used to promote several kinds of infrastructure development, including that which will attract employment-generating industries to rural areas, and that which can contribute to meeting basic human needs in communities that remain outside of monetized economies.

TECHNOLOGY TRANSFER

A strategy to develop bioenergy at industrial scales in rural regions could be launched immediately using commercially available technologies (e.g., steam turbines) in markets with large under-utilized biomass residues available at low cost (e.g., in the cane sugar industry33). But biopower production cannot expand substantially unless such initial markets are supplemented by much larger markets based on the use of more costly, but much more widely producible feedstocks grown on dedicated plantations - markets that require high-efficiency technologies that have low per unit capital costs (e.g., BIG/GT).

Such advanced technologies can be either developed indigenously or transferred from abroad, or some mixture of both. If technology is transferred, it should be accompanied by local technological capacity-building; moreover, there should be safeguards to ensure that the technology itself, and the way it is transferred, are compatible with sustainable development goals.34 Multinational corporations (MNCs), in particular, might be considered instruments for technology transfer; for example, BIG/GT technology might be transferred via independent power companies that are joint ventures between local companies and MNCs.35

One frequently voiced criticism of MNCs is that the technologies transferred often do not serve the best interests of the host countries. While this undoubtedly has been true, it is not an intrinsic problem. Developing countries may need MNCs, but MNCs need developing-country markets even more. MNCs must "grow or die." Since many industrialized-country energy markets are growing only slowly or not at all, most prospective markets for multinational energy companies are in the developing countries. If developing countries make known their preferences and dislikes about alternative technologies and put into place appropriate institutional safeguards to prevent abuses, MNCs will have to orient their business activities accordingly. At the same time, however, MNCs will generally have to be convinced that potential bioenergy markets are large and worth pursuing.36

Table 9.4 - Busbar Electric Generation Cost in India for First-Generation BIG/GT Technology1

Cost Component

Cents per kWh

Capital2

2.10

Insurance3

0.10

Property Tax4

0,30

Labour for Plant Operation5

0.18

Maintenance6

0.40

Administration7

0.10

Fuel8

1.59

Total

4.77

1 The first-generation BIG/CC system is assumed to be a 34.0% efficient (HHV), 25.9 MWe directly-heated, atmospheric-pressure biomass gasifier (TPS) coupled directly to a gas turbine/steam turbine combined cycle based on an aeroderivative gas turbine (GE LM-2500) [Larson and Consonni, 1994], for which the installed capital cost in mass production is estimated to be $1300/kWe [Elliott and Booth, 1993].

2 Assuming a 10% real discount rate and a 30-year plant life the capital recovery factor is 10.61% per year. Baseload operation @ 75% capacity factor is assumed.

3 The annual cost of insurance is assumed to be 0.5% of the installed capital cost.

4 As is typical for the US, the annual property tax is assumed to be 1.5% of the installed capital cost.

5 It is assumed that 7 operators are needed to run the power plant, as in a US situation (see note f, Table 3, in Williams and Larson [1993]). However, unlike the US, where the cost of labour is assumed to be $22.55/hour, the cost of labour is assumed here to be $5/hour.

6 The annual maintenance cost is assumed to be 2% of the installed capital cost (see note g, Table 3, in Williams and Larson [1993]), with 40% accounted for by labour and 60% by materials.

7 The annual administrative cost is assumed to be 30% of labour costs for operation and maintenance (see note h, Table 3, in Williams and Larson [1993]).

8 For a fuel price of $1.5/GJ (HHV basis) (930 Rs/t for wood with a HHV of 20 GJ/t and an exchange rate of 31 Rs/$). That this is a reasonable cost comes from the assessment by Carpentieri, et al. [1993], who estimate that eucalyptus could be grown on 4 × 106 ha of available relatively good lands in the Northeast of Brazil at an average annual yield of 20.7 t/ha/year at a cost (including 85 km of transport) of $1.23/GJ (1991 $). To this should be added a chipping cost of $5.13/t ($0.26/GJ) (cost estimate for the US [Perlack and Wright, 1995]), bringing the total cost to $1.5/GJ for wood chips delivered to the conversion facility.

If MNCs are convinced that bioenergy technologies have large potential markets and are competitive alternatives to fossil and nuclear energy technologies, they will inevitably become agents of development through technology transfer. And, via the rural industrialization promoted by the deployment of bioenergy systems and the tax base these systems would provide, they will contribute to rural infrastructure-building.

Environmental Issues

Many people consider large-scale cultivation of biomass for energy a massive assault on nature. Environmentalists are critical of the intensive agricultural management practices that biomass energy plantations require; they are concerned about chemical contamination of groundwater, loss of soil quality, aesthetic degradation of landscapes, and loss of biological diversity. Unless such concerns can be effectively addressed so that there is wide public support for biomass energy production, it will be difficult for large-scale biomass energy systems to play a major role in the world's energy future.

Biomass can, of course, be grown for energy in ways that are environmentally undesirable. However, production of biomass for energy can also improve the land environmentally relative to present use. The environmental outcome depends on how the biomass is produced, an issue that is beginning to receive attention in a variety of fora.37

Consider first the challenge of sustaining the productivity of the land. Since harvesting biomass removes nutrients from the area planted, care must be taken to ensure that these nutrients are restored. With thermochemical processes for biomass conversion (such as BIG/GT power production), it is feasible to recover all mineral nutrients as ash at the biomass conversion facility and to return the ash to the plantation as a fertilizer. However, nitrogen lost to the atmosphere at the conversion facility must be replenished.

This can be done in a number of environmentally acceptable ways. First, when trees are the harvested crop, the leaves, twigs, and small branches in which nutrients are concentrated can be left at the site to reduce nitrogen loss; this also helps maintain soil quality and reduce erosion. Second, biomass species that fix nitrogen in the soil can be selected for the plantation or for interplanting with the primary plantation species to eliminate or reduce to low levels the need for artificial fertilizers. Biomass production for energy allows much more flexibility than agriculture in meeting fixed nitrogen requirements this way. In agriculture, the market dictates the choice of feedstocks within a narrow range of characteristics. Thermochemical energy conversion technology, on the other hand, puts few restrictions on the choice of biomass feedstock, aside from the requirement of high yield, which is needed to keep costs at acceptable levels.

Energy crops also offer flexibility in dealing with erosion and chemical pollution from herbicide use - problems that occur mainly at the time the energy crop is planted. If the energy crop is an annual crop (e.g., sorghum), the erosion and herbicide pollution problems would be similar to those for annual row-crop agriculture; cultivating such crops - for energy or for agriculture - should be avoided on erodible lands. However, potential biomass energy crops also include: a) fast-growing trees that are harvested only every three to eight years and replanted perhaps every fifteen to twenty-four years, and b) perennial grasses that are harvested annually, but replanted only once in a decade or so. Both of these alternatives tend to sharply reduce erosion as well as the need for herbicides (see Table 9.2).

Another concern is chemical pollution from the use of pesticides. Experience with plantations in tropical regions shows that careful selection of species and good plantation design and management can be helpful in controlling pests and diseases, thereby minimizing or even eliminating the use of chemical pesticides. A good plantation design will typically include areas set aside for native flora and fauna to harbour natural predators for plantation pest control, and subsections of the plantation planted with different clones and/or species. If a pest attack breaks out in one such subsection, a now common practice in well-managed plantations is to let the attack run its course and to let predators from the set-aside areas help halt the outbreak.

Biomass plantations are sometimes criticized because the range of biological species they support is much narrower than for natural forests. While this is generally true, the criticism is not always relevant. It is true if a biomass plantation replaces virgin forest. However, if a plantation is established on degraded lands, it generally can support a more diverse ecology than was possible before restoration. Similarly, if biomass energy crops replace monoculture food crops, the effect on the local ecology depends on the plantation crop species chosen, but in many cases the shift will be to a more ecologically varied landscape.

As already noted, establishing and maintaining natural reserves at plantations can be helpful in controlling pests while providing ecological benefits. However, preserving biodiversity on a regional basis will require, inter alia, land-use planning in which patches of natural vegetation are connected via a network of undisturbed corridors (e.g., riparian buffer zones, shelterbelts, and hedgerows between fields), thus, enabling species to migrate from one habitat to another. Regional-level land-use planning and landscape design can also help address aesthetic concerns sometimes expressed about extensive, contiguous monocultures.

Summary

Biomass plantation energy systems could make important contributions toward sustainable development in developing countries. Land resources appear to be sufficient to support significant biomass energy production. Restoring degraded lands (of which there are several hundred million hectares in developing countries) by converting them to biomass energy plantations is one promising approach to establishing plantations on a large scale. But other land resources might also be exploited without compromising future agricultural production requirements.

Coupled with advanced conversion technologies, such as biomass-gasifier/gas turbines for electricity production, large-scale biomass-energy plantations could contribute to sustainable development in a variety of ways. In addition to the direct employment provided by plantations, the economically competitive electricity that could be produced by such systems would act as a magnet to draw other employment- and income-generating activities into rural areas, especially energy-intensive industries that offer well-paying jobs. Privatized biomass-power generation and the industrial activities it attracts could provide a tax base to help finance rural infrastructure building that would serve to attract additional economic activities. Such tax revenues could also be used to subsidize the provision of basic human needs to communities that are currently outside of the monetized economy.

The establishment of contiguous, large-area plantations have been criticized in some regions for socio-economic disruptions, including displacing small-scale farmers from their land. Such plantations may not be essential, however, for modernized biomass production and conversion systems to play an important role in the energy economy. Small-scale farm forestry is a promising alternative approach that is growing rapidly in Brazil. In this approach, forestry companies would loan their know-how and some capital to local farmers to help them establish tree crops. Farmers are, thus, able to grow trees on some or all of their land with high yields, while reducing costs for the forestry companies. Farmers thereby maintain control over their land and gain a revenue source, while forestry companies benefit from the increased local supply of wood.

Environmental concerns must be addressed if biomass energy systems are to make important contributions to sustainable development. Such concerns include the potential impacts of intensive plantation management practices, such as chemical contamination of groundwater and loss of soil quality. The characteristics of plantations required to insure environmental sustainability will vary with local bioclimatic and socio-economic factors, but biomass energy crops - especially those that would be converted into other energy carriers via thermo-chemical processes (like gasification) - would have some inherent advantages relative to conventional annual agricultural crops in dealing with environmental concerns. These include the flexibility to mix species within stands (e.g., nitrogen-fixing varieties might be included), reduced rates of soil erosion and herbicide application due to multi-year implanting of root systems, and reduced pesticide application through use of natural predators inhabiting non-harvested natural vegetation areas adjacent to harvested stands.

NOTES

1 Eric D. Larson is Research Engineer, and Robert H. Williams is Senior Research Scientist, at the Center for Energy and Environmental Studies, Princeton University.

2 J. Goldemberg, T.B. Johansson, A.K.N. Reddy, and R.H. Williams, Energy for a Sustainable World (Delhi: Wiley-Eastern, 1988).

3 R.H. Williams, "Roles for Biomass Energy in Sustainable Development," Industrial Ecology and Global Change (Cambridge University Press, 1994), pp. 199-225.

4 The assessment was prepared as input to the United Nations Conference on Environment and Development (UNCED). The study was commissioned by the U.N. Solar Energy Group for Environment and Development (UNSEGED), a high-level group of experts convened by the United Nations under the mandate of General Assembly Resolution A/45/208, December 21, 1990. That resolution requested that UNSEGED prepare a comprehensive and analytical study on new and renewable sources of energy aimed at providing a significant input to UNCED. The study was published in 1993 as a book of 1160 pages, with 23 chapters reviewing the state-of-the-art and future of renewable energy sources and technologies: Thomas B. Johansson, Henry Kelly, Amulya K.N. Reddy, and Robert H. Williams (eds.), Renewable Energy: Sources for Fuels and Electricity (Washington: Island Press, 1993). The energy supply projections in Figure 9.2a are for the Renewables-Intensive Global Energy Scenario (RIGES) described in the Appendix to Chapter 1 in that volume. For the RIGES, the demands for electricity and for solid, liquid, and gaseous fuels were assumed fixed at the levels of demand in the "high economic growth, high energy efficiency" scenario of the Response Strategies Working Group of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, Climate Change: The IPCC Response Strategies (Washington: Island Press, 1991).

5 Analyses of Shell's Group Planning Division are used as input for long-term decision-making in the worldwide Royal Dutch/Shell group of companies.

6 E.D. Larson, "Technology for Electricity and Fuels from Biomass," Annual Review of Energy and the Environment, Vol. 18 (1993), pp. 567-630; R.H. Williams and E.D. Larson, "Advanced Gasification-Based Biomass Power Generation," in Thomas B. Johannson et al., Renewable Energy, pp. 729-85; and T.P. Elliott and R. Booth, Brazilian Biomass Power Demonstration Project, Special Project Brief (London: Shell International Petroleum Company, Shell Centre, 1993).

7 E.D. Larson and S. Consonni, "Biomass-Gasifier/Aeroderivative Gas Turbine Combined Cycle Power Generation," presented at BioResources '94, Bangalore, India, October 3-7, 1994; R.H. Williams, "Roles for Biomass Energy in Sustainable Development;" and A.E. Carpentieri, E.D. Larson, and J. Woods, "Future Biomass-Based Electricity Supply in Northeast Brazil," Biomass and Bioenergy 4(3) (1993), pp. 149-73.

8 T.B. Johansson, H. Kelly, A.K.N. Reddy, and R.H. Williams, "Renewable Fuels and Electricity for a Growing World Economy: Defining and Achieving the Potential," Chapter 1, pp. 1-71, and "A Renewables-Intensive Global Energy Scenario," Appendix to Chapter 1, pp. 1071-1142, in T.B. Johansson et al. (eds.), Renewable Energy; D.O. Hall, F. Rosillo-Calle, R.H. Williams, and J. Woods, "Biomass for Energy: Supply Prospects," in T.B. Johannson et al. (eds.), Renewable Energy, pp. 593-652; R.H. Williams, "Roles for Biomass Energy in Sustainable Development;" N.H. Ravindranath and D.O. Hall, Biomass, Energy and Environment: A Developing Country Perspective from India, manuscript submitted to Oxford University Press, September 1994.

9 A. Grainger, "Estimating Areas of Degraded Tropical Lands Requiring Replenishment of Forest Cover," International Tree Crops Journal, Vol. 5 (1988), pp. 31-61; A. Grainger, "Modeling the Impact of Alternative Afforestation Strategies to Reduce Carbon Emissions," Proceedings of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change Conference on Tropical Forestry Response Options to Climate Change, Report No. 20P-2003 (Washington: Environmental Protection Agency, Office of Policy Analysis, 1990); and L.R. Oldeman et al., World Map of the Status of Human Induced Soil Degradation, International Soil Reference and Information Center and United Nations Environment Programme (April 1991).

10 R.A. Houghton, "The Future Role of Tropical Forests in Affecting the Carbon Dioxide Concentration of the Atmosphere," Ambio 19(4) (1990), pp. 204-09.

11 Ministerial Conference on Atmospheric Pollution and Climate Change, "The Noordwijk Declaration on Atmospheric Pollution and Climate Change," Noordwijk, The Netherlands (November 1989).

12 Office of Technology Assessment (OTA) of the U.S. Congress, Technologies to Sustain Tropical Forest Resources and Biological Diversity, OTA-F-515 (Washington: Government Printing Office, 1992); WE. Parham, P.J. Durana, and A.L. Hess (eds.), "Improving Degraded Lands: Promising Experiences from South China," Bishop Museum Bulletin in Botany, Vol. 3, The Bishop Museum, Honolulu, Hawaii (1993).

13 D.O. Hall et al., "Biomass for Energy."

14 P.E. Waggoner, How Much Land Can Ten Billion People Spare for Nature? (Ames, Iowa: Council for Agricultural Science and Technology, February 1994).

15 U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA), "Production, Supply, and Distribution Database" (diskette), Economic Research Service, USDA, Washington (September 1994).

16 These figures assume the most recent published World Bank population projections, which show population growing from 5.52 billion in 1993, to 9.58 billion in 2050, to 11.0 billion in 2100. See E. Bos, M.T. Vu, E. Massiah, and R.A. Bulatao, World Population Projections, 1994-95 Edition (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1994).

17 C.I. Marrison and E.D. Larson, "A Preliminary Estimate of the Biomass Energy Production Potential in Africa for 2025," (submitted to Biomass and Bioenergy), Center for Energy and Environmental Studies, Princeton University, March 23, 1995.

18 E.D. Larson, C.I. Marrison, and R.H. Williams, "CO2 Mitigation Potential of Biomass Energy Plantations in Developing Regions," forthcoming report (Princeton: Center for Energy and Environmental Studies, Princeton University, May 1995).

19 Divisao de Projetos de Fontes Alternativas, Estudos de Florestament no Semiarido Nordestino, Companhia Hidroelectrica do Sao Francisco, Recife, Brazil, (November 1985); and A.E. Carpentieri et al., "Future Biomass-Based Electricity Supply in Northeast Brazil."

20 A.E. Carpentieri et al., Future Biomass-Based Electricity Supply in Northeast Brazil."

21 L.R. Oldeman et al., World Map of the Status of Human Induced Soil Degradation, International Soil Reference and Information Center and United Nations Environment Programme (April 1991).

22 D.G. Fereira, H.P. Melo, F.R. Rodrigues Neto, P.J.S. do Nascimento, and V. Rodrigues, A Desertificacao do Nordeste do Brasil: Diagnostico e Perspectiva, Nucleo de Pesquisa e Controle da Desertificacao do Nordeste, Universidade Federal do Piaui, Teresina, Piaui, Brazil (1994).

23 N.H. Ravindranath and D.O. Hall, Biomass, Energy and Environment.

24 World Resources Institute, World Resources, 1994-95 (New York: Oxford University Press, 1994).

25 T.P. Elliott and R. Booth, Brazilian Biomass Power Demonstration Project; and R.H. Williams and E.D. Larson, "Advanced Gasification-Based Biomass Power Generation."

26 E.D. Larson and S. Consonni, "Biomass-Gasifier/Aeroderivative Gas Turbine Combined Cycle Power Generation."

27 A.E. Carpentieri et al., "Future Biomass-Based Electricity Supply in Northeast Brazil."

28 According to the U.S. Census Bureau, the average revenue per hectare for soybean production in the United States between 1990 and 1992 was $486/ha (Statistical Abstract of the United States: 1993, 113th edition, Washington 1993). The revenue might be similar in Brazil, since state-of-the-art yields for soybean production in Brazil are probably comparable to U.S. yields.

29 The comparison of soybeans with biomass production does not imply that the two would compete for the same land. In fact, as discussed elsewhere, it might be desirable to target degraded areas for multi-year rotation biomass energy production. Such areas may not be suitable for an annual crop like soybeans.

30 E.D. Larson, L.C.E. Rodriguez, and T.R. de Azevedo, "Farm Forestry in Brazil," presented at BioResources '94, Bangalore, India, October 3-7, 1994.

31 Establishing rural biopower systems would require at least the minimum level of infrastructure development associated with biomass plantations. Where industrial plantations have been successful today, the concomitant development of some infrastructure serving all locals is cited as one of the most important reasons for their success. See C. Sargent and S. Bass (eds.), Plantation Politics: Forest Plantations in Development (London: Earthscan Publications, 1992). However, such development would be relatively minor compared to the infrastructure development that could be supported through tax revenues, as discussed here.

32 The demand for new generating capacity in developing countries from 1989 to 1999 was expected to grow at an average rate of 6.1 per cent per year, with new capacity in this period added at an average rate of 38 GWe per year. See E.A. Moore and Smith, "Capital Expenditures for Electric Power in the Developing Countries in the 1990s," Energy Series Paper No. 21, Industry and Energy Department (Washington: World Bank, February 1990), with an associated present value capital requirement of over $0.2 trillion (assuming $1000/kW installed cost and 10 per cent discount rate).

33 High-pressure steam-turbine-based cogeneration systems have already been installed in some cane sugar factories worldwide. See E.D. Larson, R.H. Williams, J.M. Ogden, and M.G. Hylton, "Biomass-Gasifier Steam-Injected Gas Turbine Cogeneration for the Cane Sugar Industry" in D.L. Klass (ed.), Energy from Biomass and Wastes XIV (Chicago: Institute of Gas Technology, 1991).

34 T.B. Johansson et al., "Renewable Fuels and Electricity for a Growing World Economy," and "A Renewables-Intensive Global Energy Scenario," Appendix.

35 Alternatively, MNCs might be involved only as vendors selling technology to locally-based power companies, but this model may be a less effective instrument for technology transfer. The alternative proposed here, of involving MNCs as partners in independent power companies, gives the MNCs "cradle-to-grave" responsibility for helping manage the technologies being transferred and would facilitate access to internationally based maintenance services, if and as needed.

36 Despite the advances being made with modernized bioenergy technologies, the notion that biomass can come to play major roles in the overall energy economy flies in the face of conventional wisdom in the fossil energy circles where most MNCs move. In these circles, it is generally believed that because of (i) the low efficiency of photosynthesis and (ii) the low energy density of biomass compared to conventional fossil fuels, biomass will always remain a minor energy source.

37 J. Beyea, J. Cook, D.O. Hall, R.H. Socolow, and R.H. Williams, Toward Ecological Guidelines for Large-Scale Biomass Energy Development, Report of a Workshop for Engineers, Ecologists, and Policymakers Convened by the National Audubon Society and Princeton University, May 6, 1991; J. Davidson, Bioenergy Tree Plantations in the Tropics: Ecological Implications and Impacts, IUCN (International Union for the Conservation of Nature), Gland, Switzerland and Cambridge, UK, 1987; L. Gustafsson (ed.), "Environmental Aspects of Energy Forest Cultivation," special issue of Biomass and Bioenergy, 6(1/2) (1994); OTA, Technologies to Sustain Tropical Forest Resources; J. Sawyer, Plantations in the Tropics: Environmental Concerns, IUCN, Gland, Switzerland and Cambridge, UK (1993); Shell and WWF, Shell/WWF Tree Plantation Review, Shell International Petroleum Company, Shell Centre, London, and World Wildlife Fund for Nature, Surrey, UK (June 1993); World Energy Council, New and Renewable Energy Sources: A Guide to the Future (London: Kogan Page, 1993).

10. Converting Biomass to Liquid Fuels: Making Ethanol from Sugar Cane in Brazil

ISAIAS DE CARVALHO MACEDO1

Considered simply from the standpoint of a renewable-intensive energy future, biomass would be a widely used fuel of choice.2 It would be grown on a sustainable basis, and converted with high efficiency to fuels or electricity. However, the possible effects of widespread use of biomass must be analyzed from a broader perspective, including aspects not usually within the scope of conventional economic analyses.

The most commonly cited benefits of biomass use are reductions in air pollution and carbon dioxide, and diversification of fuel supply. An important additional consequence of biomass utilization for energy is related to its ability to promote jobs in rural areas, even for unskilled workers.

This case study analyzes the "large-scale" production of fuel ethanol from sugar cane in Brazil from the perspective of job creation. It is estimated that ethanol production corresponds to nearly 700,000 jobs in Brazil, 75 per cent of them direct jobs. Technological and economic issues make so-called "large scale" biomass conversion to energy in fact a large collection of small-scale systems; in the Brazilian case, this corresponds to the scale of agriculture generally. The socio-economic differences among ethanol-producing regions in Brazil give each of the regions different equilibrium points in the trade-off between job quality and number of jobs.

The ethanol programme has been an important factor in creating job opportunities, in both more and less developed regions of Brazil. In some regions, it has been remarkable at evolving from lower to higher-quality jobs, reducing seasonal unemployment, increasing wages and social benefits, and introducing new technologies in a timely way.

The Fuel Ethanol Programme

One of the largest commercial efforts to convert biomass to energy anywhere in the world today is the substitution of sugar-cane-based ethanol for gasoline in passenger cars in Brazil.

Fuel for cars and light vehicles in Brazil is either neat-ethanol (94 per cent ethanol, 6 per cent water) or gasohol (78 per cent gasoline, 22 per cent ethanol). The programme to promote ethanol production was established in 1975 to reduce the country's dependence on imported oil, and to help stabilize sugar production in the context of cyclical international prices; it includes government-sponsored incentives to promote private production. By 1989, production reached 12 million cubic metres annually and continues at that level.

The creation of new skilled and unskilled jobs was an important part of the programme's objective from the start. Additionally, the programme is almost entirely based on locally manufactured equipment, helping to establish a strong agro-industrial system, with a significant number of indirect jobs. It has demonstrated technological developments, in both agriculture and cane processing, leading to lower ethanol costs and the possibility of a large surplus in biomass-based (bagasse and trash) electricity. This could contribute to creating a carbon-dioxide-free energy source.

The two-decade-long experience has been important in its many positive aspects as well as in its shortcomings. It has helped to reduce oil imports, to stabilize and promote the growth of the sugar industry, to create quality jobs, and to reduce automobile pollution in urban areas. It is a model for biomass-to-energy programmes in Brazil and elsewhere. It has provided valuable information about the trade-offs in using land for food or energy, as well as about the number and quality of jobs the renewable energy industry can create.3

Converting Biomass to Energy

The size of any biomass-based energy production system is determined by at least two factors: the energy conversion (industrial) unit must have a minimum size to achieve a reasonable efficiency, but transportation costs set an upper limit to how much biomass is efficiently available. This is very important for wood-to-electricity systems (leading to development of wood gasifiers and gas turbines), for higher efficiencies at low power levels); and it is also true for sugar cane to ethanol systems.

Thus, the so-called large-scale ethanol production system in Brazil is actually composed of a large number (approximately 400) of industrial units, with cane production areas in the range of 5,000 to 50,000 hectares. This much smaller-scale system is further decentralized by the fact that sugar cane is produced by more than 60,000 suppliers. External suppliers produced approximately 38 per cent of the sugar processed in 1986, with mill owners themselves providing approximately 62 per cent.4

The seasonality of sugar cane production has a big impact on its ability to create high quality jobs. Climatic conditions and agronomic characteristics of the crop limit the harvesting season to six months out of the year in Brazil. The amount of manpower needed during the harvesting and the off season is largely determined by the level of agricultural technology employed. Because the work associated with sugar cane production is highly seasonal, jobs tend to be temporary; this, in turn, leads to high turnover, difficulty in training and, consequently, low wages.

The large number of cane growers (varying from small to very large in terms of production area), the seasonal nature of the jobs, and the fact that two thirds of the cost of ethanol comes from the cost of the sugar cane mean that employment in this sector resembles that in the conventional agricultural sector in Brazil. In fact, employment levels, costs, and wages are always compared to those of "other crops."

Analyses conducted in 1990 showed that, on average, direct labour and social taxes made up 21 to 24 per cent of the total cost of sugar cane production (including land, capital charges, and other fixed and variable costs). After including all the costs (capital, commercial, labour, and social taxes) associated with processing the cane into ethanol, direct labour and social taxes account for 20 to 25 per cent of the cost of producing ethanol (both growing and processing it). Agricultural labour and social taxes account for more than 60 per cent of total labour costs.5

Wage and training levels in the sugar cane processing industry are equivalent to those in other medium to large food industries. As in agriculture, the number of jobs and their quality are strongly influenced by the technology level (regional differences in Brazil can be very large). The distribution systems for ethanol are identical to oil-based fuel distribution; they contribute to job creation in proportion to the amount of fuel utilized. (In recent years, approximately 50 per cent of the fuel utilized by light vehicles, including automobiles, is ethanol, 50 per cent gasoline.)

Thus, in terms of job creation and the quality of jobs created, large-scale ethanol production from sugar cane acts like a large number of small to large agribusiness units. The result is a much larger number of jobs per unit of energy produced than in conventional oil-based fuel production systems; these jobs are also more diversified and decentralized than jobs in the oil sector.

The Labour Market in Brazil

An assessment of employment in the ethanol sector in Brazil must consider the context (labour conditions in the agricultural sector, and in the food industry). Wages, family income, seasonality, and other factors must be examined in relation to comparable activities.

Official unemployment rates in Brazil have been low. The average for the 1980s was 5 per cent (with a low of 3 per cent in 1989, and a high of 8 per cent in 1981).6 However, the disguised unemployment rate during the same period was high: in 1988, 44 per cent of workers in agriculture, 6 per cent in industry, and 15 per cent in services received less than the official (reference) minimum wage (at that time, US$53 per month). Only 20 per cent of workers in industry and services, and 5 per cent of agricultural workers, received more than US$265 per month.

There are significant regional differences; among the main sugar cane producing areas, Sao Paulo, which produces approximately 60 per cent of Brazil's sugar cane, has the highest salaries. Although both the official minimum wage and the actual wages received are higher today than in 1988, this analysis uses the 1988 data when analyzing jobs in the ethanol industry during the same period.

In 1988, 36.1 per cent of the population in Brazil had a family income of less than US$106 per month; 67.3 per cent had less than US$265 per month; and 94.3 per cent less than US$1,060 per month.

Job Creation

Sugar and ethanol production have in common the costs of sugar cane production, delivery to the mill, cane preparation, milling, and utilities. Although the figures used here are for the sugar cane industry as a whole, they serve as an adequate proxy for the costs of ethanol production. As mentioned before, more than 60 per cent of the sugar cane produced today is for ethanol.

The state of Sao Paulo has the highest technology level and produces 60 per cent of Brazil's sugar cane.7 Estimates indicate that every 1 million tonnes of sugar cane processed per year generates 2,200 direct jobs (1,600 in agriculture, and 600 in industry). Agricultural supervisors and skilled industrial workers account for 30 per cent; medium-skill workers (e.g., truck and tractor drivers) account for 10 per cent; and unskilled labourers (doing planting, cultivating, and harvesting, and low-level industrial work) account for the remaining 60 per cent.

Another 660 indirect jobs (equipment manufacture, engineering, repair and maintenance in external shops, and chemical supplies manufacture) are created for every 1 million tonnes of sugar cane processed. In Sao Paulo, where 140 million tonnes of sugar cane are processed every year, this leads to the creation of a total of 380,000 jobs.8

For Brazil as a whole, estimates of the number of jobs created are higher, because in the Northeast and some other regions, the amount of labour per unit of cane processed is much higher. Lower land productivity and differences in worker efficiency and technology levels mean up to three times as many jobs per unit of cane processed may be created. One estimate suggests that sugar cane agribusiness in Brazil as a whole created 800,000 direct jobs and 250,000 indirect jobs in 1990; two thirds - or 700,000 - of these jobs can be attributed to ethanol production.9

These figures are impressive in themselves, but their impact is even greater because the jobs are dispersed in a large number of places. In 1991, an average of 15.6 per cent of the new jobs in the 357 towns with ethanol distillery projects (8 per cent of the municipalities in Brazil) were associated with ethanol production; in the Midwest region, today's expanding agricultural frontier, up to 28 per cent of new jobs are associated with ethanol production.10

Regional differences in the labour market, particularly in technology, account for differences in the number of jobs created per unit of energy produced, differences in wages, and in the overall quality of the jobs created. For example, the competition for manpower among various sectors of the economy in Sao Paulo led to higher wages and better working conditions for the cane cutters; however, the number of jobs per tonne of sugar cane is much smaller than in the Northeast because of greater efficiency (training, equipment) and mechanization. Similarly, gradual automation, higher rates of productivity, and conversion efficiencies lead to fewer industrial jobs in producing and processing cane.

In the mid-1980s, a study by the University of Sao Paulo examined the effect of ethanol production on fifteen towns located in the three main ethanol producing regions. In all cases, job creation induced population growth, in most cases reversing migration to large urban areas. Only two places showed land ownership concentration. Also, in only two places was sugar cane substituted for food production. Overall, the impact on population was considered highly positive (more jobs, taxes leading to better infrastructure) in the central and southern parts of Brazil, but smaller in other regions.11

The Quality of the Jobs Created

Job quality must be assessed in the context of other employment sectors. In Sao Paulo, the job responsible for the largest proportion of unskilled labour (cane cutting) generated an average income of US$140 per month. This is higher than the average salary of 86 per cent of agricultural workers, 49 per cent of industrial workers, and 56 per cent of workers in the service sector in Brazil as a whole.

Borges estimates that the family income of cane cutters is $220 per month.12 This is 50 per cent higher than the average family wage in Brazil. But the seasonal nature of the jobs means that during the harvesting season average family wage is $280 per month; during the off season, it is only $160 per month. Special legislation has mandated that 1 per cent of the net sugar cane price and 2 per cent of the net ethanol price be used for assistance in improving services for sugar cane workers (e.g., medical, dental, pharmaceutical, better sanitary conditions).

The seasonal nature of agricultural jobs makes systematic training and career development difficult. The seasonality coefficient for agricultural workers in sugar cane, defined as the ratio between manpower in the harvesting season and in the off season period, was estimated at 2.2 at the end of the 1970s in Sao Paulo.13 At that time, coffee was the only major crop in Sao Paulo with a lower seasonality index (2.0).

Many factors contributed to lowering the seasonality coefficient of Sao Paulo's sugar cane workers throughout the 1980s. Three are particularly noteworthy. First, more labour was required during the off-season to grow food crops in alternative rotation. Second, harvesting workers were increasingly used for off-season jobs in maintenance and conservation. Third, a smaller number of workers was required during the harvesting season, both because the yield from manual cutting was increasing (from 4.5 tonnes to 7 tonnes per person per day) and because of increased mechanized harvesting (in 1992, 15 per cent of the total area harvested in Sao Paulo). By the end of the 1980s, the seasonality coefficient was estimated to be 1.8.14 More recently, the average seasonality coefficient for eight sugar mills in Sao Paulo was estimated to be only 1.3.15

The trend is quite clear. With increased mechanization of harvesting and increasing yields for manual cutting, it seems possible that eventually most agricultural jobs will be permanent. This will promote training and career planning, and lead to much higher wages (but fewer jobs). This trend is not as evident in some other regions. In the Northeast, for example, labour costs are lower and technical issues make mechanization more difficult.

In Sao Paulo, 23 per cent of the cane cutters, which comprises the largest category of unskilled workers, are women.16 In the Northeast, the proportion is similar and comparable to that in other unskilled job categories.

The balance between mechanization and the number and quality of new jobs created by the ethanol industry is likely to be a key issue for the coming years.17 A law requiring the cutting of unburnt sugar cane could accelerate mechanical harvesting, as could increasing labour costs. Already, in the state of Sao Paulo, the labour market cannot supply the required amount of unskilled workers.

Seasonality has a smaller impact on industrial workers, who make up less than 30 per cent of the total number of workers associated with ethanol production. Industrial workers are used in-house during the off season for repair and maintenance jobs.

Investing in Job Creation

Estimates of the amount of investment needed for job creation in the ethanol industry reflect regional differences in wages, employee productivity, and technology. Values as low as US$11,000 per job have been reported.18 These are probably appropriate for the Northeast region. However, for Sao Paulo, analyses indicate that investments of $23,000 per job are needed (not including the investment in land) up to $45,000 per job (including the investment in land and achieving full employment).19

In comparison, the average investment needed for job creation in the 35 main sectors of the Brazilian economy in 1991 varied from $10,000 to $125,000 per job, thus, averaging $41,000.20 Even including land costs, only 14 sectors would provide jobs with lower investment than the ethanol industry. When the less developed areas are considered, the investment cost per job in the ethanol industry becomes much lower than the Brazilian average.

Biomass Energy Generation in the Future

In the sugar-cane-to-ethanol industry, a large portion of the potential jobs are in the growing of sugar cane. Cane harvesting can be handled by a number of processes, varying from manual cutting of burnt cane (by far, the most used in the world) to almost entirely mechanized harvesting. The cost of labour is the key to determining the balance between manual and mechanized harvesting, with mechanization resulting in fewer, but higher quality, jobs. This is the trend in the Sao Paulo region.

A number of developments, however, could change the picture considerably. The worldwide practice of burning sugar cane fields prior to harvesting in order to improve productivity has been severely questioned for environmental reasons. Although there seems to be no real reason for concern (carbon dioxide from burning is entirely recycled, and local environmental problems consist only of the nuisance created by carbon particles), another argument must be considered: the renewable energy lost in burning could be used if suitable harvesting and transportation systems could be designed to handle the green cane and trash economically. Such a more efficient use of biomass for power generation could impact larger areas besides Brazil and would have important consequences for job creation and quality in many places.

The subject has been extensively analyzed.21 Technologies for converting trash to energy could include conventional high pressure steam cycles, working year-round with stored trash (or bagasse). In the short term, ethanol production from the ligno-cellulosic material or even power generation with advanced gasification/gas turbine cycles has been considered. It has been demonstrated that it is possible to design sufficiently low cost (US$1 per GJ) trash recovery systems to make power production from trash economically feasible in Brazil.22 Such systems could greatly improve the economics of producing energy from sugar cane.23

The implications for the labour market are the following: First, harvesting would be mechanized; much higher (unskilled) manpower would be needed for the manual cutting of unburnt cane than is available in Sao Paulo today. In some countries, it may be possible to keep manual cutting; however, the increased seasonality index (and necessarily low wages) would result in low-quality jobs.

Second, mechanization would not be as simple as the use of today's green cane harvesters; it would include trash recovery, transportation, and conditioning.

Third, the power generation sector of the cane processing units would operate for at least eleven months out of the year (the accepted standard for this industry). Seasonality would be reduced; jobs would be created for bagasse/trash handling, storing, and power station operation.

Studies on the potential reduction of jobs due to mechanized harvesting in Brazil are not conclusive, except for some specific regions. They usually consider only the loss in unskilled jobs (cane cutting); this is a realistic approach if trash is left in the field without further utilization. However, the use of trash for energy would create a new industry consisting of fewer, higher quality jobs.

One recent analysis of job losses due to mechanical harvesting concluded that if mechanization increases from its current level of 15 per cent to 46 per cent in Sao Paulo, it would result in a 15 per cent loss of jobs. One specific region (Ribeirao Preto), already 30 per cent mechanized, would lose 31 per cent of the jobs if mechanization reaches 60 per cent of the total. Again, no consideration is given to higher quality job creation.24

In 1991, Borges estimated that if 85 per cent of the total sugar cane area in Sao Paulo is mechanized, the number of jobs will drop 25 to 30 per cent. He assumed that an unburnt cane harvester could replace 50 workers (with 1990 technology and an average productivity of 7 tonnes per person per day in Sao Paulo). He estimated that the number of truck drivers and other equipment operators would increase by 25 to 80 per cent, depending on the technology used (trash bailing and independent transportation, or cane with trash transportation). Not included were the permanent higher quality jobs created in the power generator sector or the indirect jobs for equipment production and maintenance. Although these figures are preliminary and based on hypotheses that are changing with new technology inputs, they provide a useful first estimate.25

Conclusion

The ethanol programme in Brazil shows that large-scale biomass systems can have strong positive impacts on job creation and quality. Adjustments in the relationship between job quality and the number of agricultural jobs can be made to fit the local labour market; new technologies make it possible to use more skilled workers, reducing the number of workers for the same job. The trend in Brazil is irreversibly toward better technology and higher quality, but fewer jobs.

The ethanol programme has helped reverse migration to large urban areas and increase the overall quality of life in many small towns. During its nearly twenty years, the programme has been extensively analyzed, criticized, and improved in many aspects (legal, tributary, technological).

In designing large-scale decentralized programmes to convert biomass to energy (such as the proposed biomass gasification - gas turbine power generation systems), other countries should examine Brazil's experience in order to gain maximum benefit.

NOTES

1 Isaias de Carvalho Macedo is Technology Manager at Centro de Tecnologia Copersucar, SPaulo.

2 T.B. Johansson, H. Kelly, A.K.N. Reddy, and R.H. Williams, "Renewable Fuels and Electricity for A Growing World Economy," in Renewable Energy Sources for Fuels and Electricity (Washington, D.C: Island Press, 1993).

3 For a detailed description of the ethanol programme's social and political dynamics, including its purpose; the incentive structure; the relative positions of government, the automotive industry, the oil industry, and ethanol producers; legislation; market forces; and current trends and evolution, see J. Goldemberg, L. Monaco, and I. Macedo, "The Brazilian Fuel-Alcohol Programme, in Renewable Energy Sources for Fuels and Electricity (Washington: Island Press, 1993).

4 J.M. Borges, "The Brazilian Energy Programme: Foundations, Results, Perspectives," Energy Sources, 12: 451-461.

5 Funda GetVargas, Sistema Custo/Pre- cool Hidratado (SPaulo: Autas, 1994).

6 J.M. Borges, "Gera de Empregos na Agro-Inda Canavieira," in Desenvolvimento em Harmonia com o Meio Ambiente (Rio de Janeiro: Funda Brasileira Para a Conserva de Natureza, 1992).

7 J.M. Borges, "The Effect on Labour and Social Issues of Electricity Sales in the Brazilian Sugarcane Industry," Proceedings of the International Conference on Energy from Sugarcane (Hawaii: Winrock International, 1991).

8 Borges, "The Effect on Labour and Social Issues."

9 J. Magalhaes, R. Machado, N. Kuperman, Polcas Econas, Empr e Distribui de Renda na Amca Latina (Rio de Janeiro: Editora Vozes, 1991).

10 J. Magalhaes, R. Machado, N. Kuperman, Polcas Econas.

11 B. Johnson, T. Wright. Impactos Comunitos do Pro-cool, Report to Secretaria de Tecnologia Industrial - Ministo de Industria e Com- Faculdade de Economia Administra, Universidade de SPaulo (SPaulo, 1983).

12 J.M. Borges, "The Effect on Labour and Social Issues."

13 Assoc. Indas de Aar e cool (AIAA), Aar e cool: Energia para um Crescimento Econo Auto-Sustentado (SPaulo: Datagro, 1991).

14 J.M. Borges, "The Effect on Labour and Social Issues."

15 J.C. Marques, Copersucar Economic Advisory, SPaulo (personal communication, 1995).

16 J.C. Marques (personal communication).

17 J.M. Borges, "The Brazilian Alcohol Programme"; A Veiga, Z. Santos, M. Otani, and R. Yoshii, "Anse da Mecaniza do Cone da Cana de Aar no Estado de SPaulo," Informas Econas, 24:10 (SPaulo, 1991).

18 AIAA, Aar e cool.

19 J.M. Borges, Gera de Empregos.

20 J.M. Borges, "The Effect on Labour and Social Issues."

21 Centro de Tecnologia Copersucar, Relat Tico Interno: Convo EletrobrCopersucar: Alternativas de Co-gera (SPaulo: Piracicaba, 1991).

22 Centro de Tecnologia Copersucar, Brazilian Biomass Power Generation: Sugar Cane Bagasse Extension, Report to the GEF/UNDP (SPaulo: Piracicaba, 1993).

23 J. Ogden and M. Fulmer, Assessment of New Technologies for Co-Production of Alcohol, Sugar and Electricity from Sugar Cane, PU/CEES Report No. 250 (Princeton: Princeton University, 1990).

24 A Veiga, Z. Santos, M. Otani, R. Yoshii, Anse da Mecaniza do Corte da Cana de Aar.

25 J.M. Borges, "The Effect on Labour and Social Issues."