Understanding the labour market in Kenya
Paul Collier and Deepak Lal, Labour and Poverty in Kenya
1900-1980, Clarendon Press, Oxford, 1986, 296 pp., £27.50.
This book is part of a series of case studies on labour markets
in developing countries. It supplies an enormous amount of historical and
economic information on the labour market in Kenya, and at the same time applies
a methodology to labour market analysis in developing countries with the aim of
testing the neoclassical approach.
The first three chapters are on the historical development of
the labour market in Kenya, which the authors divide into three different
periods: coercion (1800-1948), compassion (1948- 1968), and competition
(1968-1980).
During the coercion period Kenyan society was stratified along
racial lines. The whites monopolized the export of agricultural commodities and
the most important posts in the administration: the Asians were employed in the
internal commerce and secondary roles in administration; and the Africans served
as the unskilled labour both urban and rural.
The compassion period was characterized by the recognition of
trade unions and the introduction of minimum wage laws and a protective labour
code. In other words, the labour market was brought under institutional control,
and a deliberate wage policy to modify income distribution was implemented.
The most recent period, competition, occurred during a period of
rapid but uneven economic growth. Institutional control over the labour market
was not abandoned, but the formal apparatus of regulation "gradually became a
validation of market forces rather than a constraint upon them".
The historical background outlined, it is argued, not only
allows a comparison to be made between different periods (i.e., comparative
statistics), but also accounts for the dynamic forces relating one period to
another. As followers of Sir John Hicks in methodology, the authors declare that
their interest in economic history is confined to its implications for economic
analysis.
The model presented starts from two assumptions about the
"vital" processes for the development of Kenya. According to the authors,
development is, first, connected to the efficient growth of smallholder
agriculture, linked to investment and innovation rates. Second, it is connected
to the efficient skill formation of the urban labour force. However, these two
processes have been "attenuated" because of the wage policy implemented during
the compassionate period. Wage policy has increased the urban-rural
differentials, creating two main effects. While it has somewhat distorted urban
wage structures, especially by reducing seniority premiums, it has also
increased rural-urban migration.
While other studies on the Kenya labour market stress that this
migration process involved an increase of urban poverty and unemployment, the
authors underline that its main effect was to provide rural smallholders with
the financial means to undertake the development process. Urban workers, thanks
to the income shares they obtained because of the wage policy applied, were able
to provide the resources for financing rural innovation, in the majority of
cases on a family linkage basis. The flows of financial resources from urban
workers to rural smallholders allowed innovation and investment in agriculture
to take place.
In the latest period, the competitive rural-urban wage
differentials were reduced. The returns from education fell, increasing the
overall number of unskilled employees. However, the reduction in urban-rural
wage differentials had a beneficial effect on skill formation at the firm level.
While in the previous period the inter-urban wage differentials between senior
and junior workers narrowed, reducing the incentive to acquire firm-specific
skills, the reduction in wages for the urban unskilled workers again led to a
seniority and skill differential, and therefore meant an incentive to acquire
skills. Urban wage differentials, according to the authors, have proven to be a
fundamental element in developing human capital.
The conclusions and policy implications of this analysis are
direct. The authors believe in the functioning of the labour market as an
equilibrating force. Wages are not considered rigid despite the imbalances in
the demand and supply of different types of labour. The authors criticize
alternative approaches: "The policy implications of the segmented labour market
type view are grossly misleading. In this view these wage differentials do not
serve any useful efficiency function, although they do determine the
distribution of income. Hence, it is implied, public policy can and should
squeeze these differentials, so that the resulting income distribution is made
to conform to public preferences.... This conclusion would be as unwarranted as
its premise. At least in Kenya, its post-war economic history provides an ample
demonstration of the costs which are associated with the various wage policies
aimed in part at affecting the income distribution."
Intervention in labour markets proved to be counterproductive.
After their very detailed analysis, which includes recognition of the role of
institutions (the authors argue that "trade unions serve an efficiency function,
and to that extent would have to be invented if they did not already exist"),
the policies they recommend do not differ from an ancient and well-known
laissez-faire.
A last remark on the fact that the authors - who declare
themselves to be new neo-classical economists - refer to the views of their
opponents as "conventional wisdom". In present-day economics, it seems that
"conventional wisdom" has become synonymous with "other school traditions" -
whatever they are.
Daniele
Archibugi